Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
For use at 11:00 a.m. EST
February 19, 2021
Monetary Policy rePort
February 19, 2021
Letter of transmittaL
B  G  
F R S
Washington, D.C., February 19, 2021
T P   S
T S   H  R
The Board of Governors is pleased to submit its Monetary Policy Report pursuant to
section 2B of the Federal Reserve Act.
Sincerely,
Jerome H. Powell, Chair
Statement on Longer-run goaLS and monetary PoLicy Strategy
Adopted effective January24, 2012; as amended effective January26, 2021
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) is rmly committed to fullling its statutory mandate from
the Congress of promoting maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates. The
Committee seeks to explain its monetary policy decisions to the public as clearly as possible. Such clarity
facilitates well-informed decisionmaking by households and businesses, reduces economic and nancial
uncertainty, increases the eectiveness of monetary policy, and enhances transparency and accountability,
which are essential in a democratic society.
Employment, ination, and long-term interest rates uctuate over time in response to economic and nancial
disturbances. Monetary policy plays an important role in stabilizing the economy in response to these
disturbances. The Committee’s primary means of adjusting the stance of monetary policy is through changes
in the target range for the federal funds rate. The Committee judges that the level of the federal funds rate
consistent with maximum employment and price stability over the longer run has declined relative to its
historical average. Therefore, the federal funds rate is likely to be constrained by its eective lower bound
more frequently than in the past. Owing in part to the proximity of interest rates to the eective lower bound,
the Committee judges that downward risks to employment and ination have increased. The Committee is
prepared to use its full range of tools to achieve its maximum employment and price stability goals.
The maximum level of employment is a broad-based and inclusive goal that is not directly measurable
and changes over time owing largely to nonmonetary factors that aect the structure and dynamics of the
labor market. Consequently, it would not be appropriate to specify a xed goal for employment; rather, the
Committee’s policy decisions must be informed by assessments of the shortfalls of employment from its
maximum level, recognizing that such assessments are necessarily uncertain and subject to revision. The
Committee considers a wide range of indicators in making these assessments.
The ination rate over the longer run is primarily determined by monetary policy, and hence the Committee
has the ability to specify a longer-run goal for ination. The Committee rearms its judgment that ination
at the rate of 2 percent, as measured by the annual change in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures, is most consistent over the longer run with the Federal Reserve’s statutory mandate. The
Committee judges that longer-term ination expectations that are well anchored at 2 percent foster price
stability and moderate long-term interest rates and enhance the Committee’s ability to promote maximum
employment in the face of signicant economic disturbances. In order to anchor longer-term ination
expectations at this level, the Committee seeks to achieve ination that averages 2 percent over time, and
therefore judges that, following periods when ination has been running persistently below 2 percent,
appropriate monetary policy will likely aim to achieve ination moderately above 2 percent for some time.
Monetary policy actions tend to inuence economic activity, employment, and prices with a lag. In setting
monetary policy, the Committee seeks over time to mitigate shortfalls of employment from the Committee’s
assessment of its maximum level and deviations of ination from its longer-run goal. Moreover, sustainably
achieving maximum employment and price stability depends on a stable nancial system. Therefore, the
Committee’s policy decisions reect its longer-run goals, its medium-term outlook, and its assessments
of the balance of risks, including risks to the nancial system that could impede the attainment of the
Committee’s goals.
The Committee’s employment and ination objectives are generally complementary. However, under
circumstances in which the Committee judges that the objectives are not complementary, it takes into account
the employment shortfalls and ination deviations and the potentially dierent time horizons over which
employment and ination are projected to return to levels judged consistent with its mandate.
The Committee intends to review these principles and to make adjustments as appropriate at its annual
organizational meeting each January, and to undertake roughly every 5 years a thorough public review of its
monetary policy strategy, tools, and communication practices.
Contents
note: This report reects information that was publicly available as of noon EST on February 17, 2021.
Unless otherwise stated, the time series in the gures extend through, for daily data, February16, 2021; for monthly
data, January2021; and, for quarterly data, 2020:Q4. In bar charts, except as noted, the change for a given period is
measured to its nal quarter from the nal quarter of the preceding period.
For gures 15, 33, and 44, note that the S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. National Home Price Index, the S&P 500 Index, and
the Dow Jones Bank Index are products of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC and/or its afliates and have been licensed for
use by the Board. Copyright © 2021 S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, a division of S&P Global, and/or its afliates. All
rights reserved. Redistribution, reproduction, and/or photocopying in whole or in part are prohibited without written
permission of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC. For more information on any of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC’s indices please
visit www.spdji.com. S&P® is a registered trademark of Standard & Poor’s Financial Services LLC, and Dow Jones® is a
registered trademark of Dow Jones Trademark Holdings LLC. Neither S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, Dow Jones Trademark
Holdings LLC, their afliates nor their third party licensors make any representation or warranty, express or implied, as to
the ability of any index to accurately represent the asset class or market sector that it purports to represent, and neither
S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, Dow Jones Trademark Holdings LLC, their afliates nor their third party licensors shall have
any liability for any errors, omissions, or interruptions of any index or the data included therein.
For gure22, neither DTCC Solutions LLC nor any of its afliates shall be responsible for any errors or omissions in any
DTCC data included in this publication, regardless of the cause, and, in no event, shall DTCC or any of its afliates be
liable for any direct, indirect, special, or consequential damages, costs, expenses, legal fees, or losses (including lost
income or lost prot, trading losses, and opportunity costs) in connection with this publication.
Summary ................................................................ 1
Economic and Financial Developments ......................................... 1
Monetary Policy ........................................................... 2
Special Topics ............................................................. 3
Part 1: Recent Economic and Financial Developments ..................... 5
Domestic Developments. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
Financial Developments .................................................... 26
International Developments ................................................. 32
Part 2: Monetary Policy ................................................. 39
Part 3: Summary of Economic Projections ............................... 49
Abbreviations ...........................................................67
List of Boxes
Monitoring Economic Activity with Nontraditional High-Frequency Indicators ............ 7
Disparities in Job Loss during the Pandemic ..................................... 12
Developments Related to Financial Stability ..................................... 30
The FOMC’s Revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy ...... 40
Monetary Policy Rules and Shortfalls from Maximum Employment .................... 45
Forecast Uncertainty ....................................................... 64
1
summary
The COVID-19 pandemic continues to
weigh heavily on economic activity and labor
markets in the United States and around
the world, even as the ongoing vaccination
campaigns oer hope for a return to more
normal conditions later this year. While
unprecedented scal and monetary stimulus
and a relaxation of rigorous social-distancing
restrictions supported a rapid rebound in the
U.S. labor market last summer, the pace of
gains has slowed and employment remains
well below pre-pandemic levels. In addition,
weak aggregate demand and low oil prices
have held down consumer price ination. In
this challenging environment, the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC) has held
its policy rate near zero and has continued
to purchase Treasury securities and agency
mortgage-backed securities to support the
economic recovery. These measures, along
with the Committee’s strong guidance on
interest rates and the balance sheet, will ensure
that monetary policy will continue to deliver
powerful support to the economy until the
recovery is complete.
Economic and Financial
Developments
Economic activity and the labor market. The
initial wave of COVID-19 infections led to a
historic contraction in economic activity as
a result of both mandatory restrictions and
voluntary changes in behavior by households
and businesses. The level of gross domestic
product (GDP) fell a cumulative 10percent
over the rst half of 2020, and the measured
unemployment rate spiked to a post–World
War II high of 14.8percent in April. As
mandatory restrictions were subsequently
relaxed and households and rms adapted
to pandemic conditions, many sectors of the
economy recovered rapidly and unemployment
fell back. Momentum slowed substantially
in the late fall and early winter, however, as
spending on many services contracted again
amid a worsening of the pandemic. All told,
GDP is currently estimated to have declined
2.5percent over the four quarters of last
year and payroll employment in January was
almost 10million jobs below pre-pandemic
levels, while the unemployment rate remained
elevated at 6.3percent and the labor force
participation rate was severely depressed.
Job losses have been most severe and
unemployment remains particularly elevated
among Hispanics, African Americans, and
other minority groups as well as those who
hold lower-wage jobs.
Ination. After declining sharply as the
pandemic struck, consumer price ination
rebounded along with economic activity, but
ination remains below pre-COVID levels and
the FOMC’s longer-run objective of 2percent.
The 12-month measure of PCE (personal
consumption expenditures) ination was
1.3percent in December, while the measure
that excludes food and energy items—so-called
core ination, which is typically less volatile
than total ination—was 1.5percent. Both
total and core ination were held down in part
by prices for services adversely aected by
the pandemic, and indicators of longer-run
ination expectations are now at similar levels
to those seen in recent years.
Financial conditions. Financial conditions
have improved notably since the spring of last
year and remain generally accommodative.
Low interest rates, the Federal Reserve’s asset
purchases, the establishment of emergency
lending facilities, and other extraordinary
actions, together with scal policy, continued
to support the ow of credit in the economy
and smooth market functioning. The nominal
Treasury yield curve steepened and equity
prices continued to increase steadily in the
second half of last year as concerns over the
resurgence in COVID-19 cases appeared to
have been outweighed by positive news about
vaccine prospects and expectations of further
2 SUMMARY
scal support. Spreads of yields on corporate
bonds over those on comparable-maturity
Treasury securities narrowed signicantly,
partly because the credit quality of rms
improved and market functioning remained
stable. Mortgage rates for households remain
near historical lows. However, nancing
conditions remain relatively tight for
households with low credit scores and for small
businesses.
Financial stability. While some nancial
vulnerabilities have increased since the start
of the pandemic, the institutions at the core
of the nancial system remain resilient.
Asset valuation pressures have returned to
or exceeded pre-pandemic levels in most
markets, including in equity, corporate bond,
and residential real estate markets. Although
government programs have supported business
and household incomes, some businesses and
households have become more vulnerable to
shocks, as earnings have fallen and borrowing
has risen. Strong capital positions before the
pandemic helped banks absorb large losses
related to the pandemic. Financial institutions,
however, may experience additional losses as
a result of rising defaults in the coming years,
and long-standing vulnerabilities at money
market mutual funds and open-end investment
funds remain unaddressed. Although some
facilities established by the Federal Reserve in
the wake of the pandemic have expired, those
remaining continue to serve as important
backstops against further stress. (See the box
“Developments Related to Financial Stability”
in Part 1.)
International developments. Mirroring the
United States, economic activity abroad
bounced back last summer after the spread
of the virus moderated and restrictions eased.
Subsequent infections and renewed restrictions
have again depressed economic activity,
however. Relative to the spring, the current
slowdown in economic activity has been
less dramatic. Fiscal and monetary policies
continue to be supportive, and people have
adapted to containment measures that have
often been less stringent than earlier.
Despite the resurgence of the pandemic in
many economies, nancial markets abroad
have recovered since the spring, buoyed
by continued strong scal and monetary
policy support and the start of vaccination
campaigns in many countries. With the
abatement of nancial stress, the broad dollar
has depreciated, more than reversing its
appreciation at the onset of the pandemic. On
balance, global equity prices have recovered
and sovereign credit spreads in emerging
market economies and in the European
periphery have narrowed. In major advanced
economies, sovereign yields remained near
historical low levels amid continued monetary
policy accommodation.
Monetary Policy
Review of the strategic framework for monetary
policy. The Federal Reserve concluded the
review of its strategic framework for monetary
policy in the second half of 2020. The review
was motivated by changes in the U.S. economy
that aect monetary policy, including the
global decline in the general level of interest
rates and the reduced sensitivity of ination
to labor market tightness. In August, the
FOMC issued a revised Statement on Longer-
Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy.
1
The revised statement acknowledges the
changes in the economy over recent decades
and articulates how policymakers are taking
these changes into account in conducting
monetary policy. In the revised statement,
the Committee indicates that it aims to attain
its statutory goals by seeking to eliminate
shortfalls from maximum employment—a
broad-based and inclusive goal—and achieve
ination that averages 2percent over time.
Achieving ination that averages 2percent
1. The statement, revised in August2020, was
unanimously rearmed at the FOMC’s January2021
meeting.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 3
over time helps ensure that longer-term
ination expectations remain well anchored at
the FOMC’s longer-run 2percent objective.
Hence, following periods when ination has
been running persistently below 2percent,
appropriate monetary policy will likely aim to
achieve ination moderately above 2percent
for some time. (See the box “The FOMC’s
Revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals and
Monetary Policy Strategy” in Part 2.)
In addition, in December the FOMC
introduced two changes to the Summary
of Economic Projections (SEP) intended
to enhance the information provided to the
public. First, the release of the full set of SEP
exhibits was accelerated by three weeks, from
the publication of the minutes three weeks
after the end of an FOMC meeting to the
day of the policy decision, the second day of
an FOMC meeting. Second, new charts were
included that display how FOMC participants’
assessments of uncertainties and risks have
evolved over time.
Interest rate policy. In light of the eects of the
continuing public health crisis on the economy
and the associated risks to the outlook, the
FOMC has maintained the target range for the
federal funds rate at 0 to ¼percent since last
March. In pursuing the strategy outlined in its
revised statement, the Committee noted that it
expects it will be appropriate to maintain this
target range until labor market conditions have
reached levels consistent with the Committee’s
assessments of maximum employment and
ination has risen to 2percent and is on track
to moderately exceed 2percent for some time.
Balance sheet policy. With the federal funds
rate near zero, the Federal Reserve has also
continued to undertake asset purchases to
increase its holdings of Treasury securities
by $80billion per month and its holdings
of agency mortgage-backed securities by
$40billion per month. These purchases
help foster smooth market functioning and
accommodative nancial conditions, thereby
supporting the ow of credit to households
and businesses. The Committee expects these
purchases to continue at least at this pace until
substantial further progress has been made
toward its maximum-employment and price-
stability goals.
In assessing the appropriate stance of
monetary policy, the Committee will continue
to monitor the implications of incoming
information for the economic outlook. The
Committee is prepared to adjust the stance of
monetary policy as appropriate if risks emerge
that could impede the attainment of the
Committee’s goals.
Special Topics
Disparities in job loss. The COVID-19 crisis
has exacerbated pre-existing disparities in
labor market outcomes across job types and
demographic groups. Job losses last spring
were disproportionately severe among lower-
wage workers, less-educated workers, and
racial and ethnic minorities, as in previous
recessions, but also among women, in contrast
to previous recessions. While all groups
have experienced at least a partial recovery
in employment rates since April2020, the
shortfall in employment remains especially
large for lower-wage workers and for
Hispanics, African Americans, and other
minority groups, and the additional childcare
burdens resulting from school closures have
weighed more heavily on womens labor
force participation than on mens labor force
participation. (See the box “Disparities in Job
Loss during the Pandemic” in Part 1.)
High-frequency indicators. The unprecedented
magnitude, speed, and nature of the
COVID-19 shock to the economy rendered
traditional statistics insucient for monitoring
economic activity in a timely manner. As a
result, policymakers turned to nontraditional
high-frequency indicators of activity,
especially for the labor market and consumer
4 SUMMARY
spending. These indicators presented a more
timely and granular picture of the drop and
subsequent rebound in economic activity last
spring. The most recent readings obtained
from those indicators suggest that economic
activity began to edge up again in January,
likely reecting in part the disbursement of
additional stimulus payments to households.
(See the box “Monitoring Economic Activity
with Nontraditional High-Frequency
Indicators” in Part 1.)
Monetary policy rules. Simple monetary policy
rules, which relate a policy interest rate to a
small number of other economic variables,
can provide useful guidance to policymakers.
This discussion presents the policy rate
prescriptions from a number of rules that have
received attention in the research literature,
many of which mechanically prescribe raising
the federal funds rate as employment rises
above estimates of its longer-run level. A rule
that instead responds only to shortfalls of
employment from assessments of its maximum
level is featured to illustrate one aspect of
the FOMC’s revised approach to policy, as
described in the revised Statement on Longer-
Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy. (See
the box “Monetary Policy Rules and Shortfalls
from Maximum Employment” in Part 2.)
5
Domestic Developments
The labor market has partially recovered
from the pandemic-induced collapse,
but the pace of improvement slowed
substantially toward the end of last year . . .
The public health crisis spurred by the
spread of COVID-19 weighed on economic
activity throughout 2020, and patterns
in the labor market reected the ebb and
ow of the virus and the actions taken by
households, businesses, and governments
to combat its spread. During the initial
stage of the pandemic in March and April,
payroll employment plunged by 22million
jobs, while the measured unemployment rate
jumped to 14.8percent—its highest level
since the Great Depression (gures 1 and2).
2
As cases subsided and early lockdowns were
relaxed, payroll employment rebounded
rapidly—particularly outside of the service
sectors—and the unemployment rate fell
back. Beginning late last year, however, the
pace of improvement in the labor market
slowed markedly amid another large wave
of COVID-19 cases. The unemployment
rate declined only 0.4percentage point from
November through January, while payroll
gains averaged just 29,000 per month, weighed
down by a contraction in the leisure and
hospitality sector, which is particularly aected
by social distancing and government-mandated
restrictions.
2. Since the beginning of the pandemic, a substantial
number of people on temporary layo, who should be
counted as unemployed, have instead been recorded as
“employed but on unpaid absence.” The Bureau of Labor
Statistics reports that, if these workers had been correctly
classied, the unemployment rate would have been
5percentage points higher in April. The misclassication
problem has abated since then, and the unemployment
rate in January was at most about ½percentage
point lower than it would have been in the absence of
misclassication.
Part 1
reCent eConomiC and finanCiaL deveLoPments
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
Percent
202120192017201520132011200920072005
2. Civilian unemployment rate
Monthly
SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
125
130
135
140
145
150
155
Millions of jobs
202120192017201520132011200920072005
1. Nonfarm payroll employment
Monthly
SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
6 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Employment-to-
population ratio
50
52
54
56
58
60
62
64
66
68
Percent
202120192017201520132011200920072005
3. Labor force participation rate and
employment-to-population ratio
Monthly
Labor force participation rate
NOTE: The labor force participation rate and the
employment-
to-population ratio are percentages of the population aged 16 and over.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
All told, the incomplete recovery left the level
of employment in January almost 10million
lower than it was a year earlier, while the
unemployment rate stood at 6.3percent—
nearly 3percentage points higher than before
the onset of the pandemic. Most recently,
high-frequency data—including initial claims
for unemployment insurance and weekly
employment data from the payroll processor
ADP—suggest modest further improvement
in the labor market in recent weeks. (For more
discussion of what high-frequency indicators
are suggesting about the current trajectory
of the economy, see the box “Monitoring
Economic Activity with Nontraditional High-
Frequency Indicators.”)
. . . and the harm has been substantial
The damage to the labor market has been
even more substantial than is indicated by
the extent of unemployment alone. The labor
force participation rate (LFPR)—the share
of the population that is either working or
actively looking for work—plunged in March
and April, as many of those who lost their
jobs were not seeking work and so were not
counted among the unemployed. Despite
recovering some over the summer, the LFPR
remains nearly 2percentage points below
its pre-pandemic level (gure3). A number
of factors appear to have contributed to the
continued weakness in the LFPR, including
a lack of job opportunities, the eects of
school closings and virtual learning on
parents’ ability to work, the health concerns
of potential workers, and a spate of early
retirements triggered by the crisis. All told,
the employment-to-population ratio—the
share of the population with jobs, regardless
of the number seeking work—in January
was 3.6percentage points below the level at
the beginning of 2020. Job losses last year
fell most heavily on lower-wage workers
and on Hispanics, African Americans,
and other minority groups. As a result,
the rise in unemployment and the decline
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 7
A. Estimates of private payroll employment growth
NOTE: ADP data are weekly and extend through February 6, 2021. BLS data are monthly.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board sta calculations using ADP, Inc., Payroll Processing Data; Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), Current
Employment Statistics (CES).
Payroll employment growth in leisure and hospitality Aggregate payroll employment growth
ADP-FRB, 4-week average
BLS CES
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
Millions of jobs, monthly rate
Feb. Apr. June Aug.Oct. Dec. Feb.
2020 2021
ADP-FRB
ADP-FRB, 4-week average
BLS CES
9
6
3
+
_
0
3
Millions of jobs, monthly rate
Feb. Apr. June Aug. Oct. Dec. Feb.
2020 2021
ADP-FRB
state of the labor market.
1
An important example is
data from the payroll processor ADP that cover roughly
20percent of private U.S. employment, a sample size
similar to the one used by the BLS to construct the CES.
Estimates of changes in employment constructed from
ADP data have tracked the of cial CES data remarkably
well since the start of the pandemic recession, and
the ADP data possess the important bene ts of being
available earlier and at a weekly frequency ( gure A,
left panel).
2
1. See, for example, Raj Chetty, John N. Friedman,
Nathaniel Hendren, Michael Stepner, and the Opportunity
Insights Team (2020), “The Economic Impacts of COVID-19:
Evidence from a New Public Database Built Using Private
Sector Data,” NBER Working Paper Series 27431 (Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, November),
https://www.nber.org/papers/w27431; and Alexander W. Bartik,
Marianne Bertrand, Feng Lin, Jesse Rothstein, and Matt Unrath
(forthcoming), “Measuring the Labor Market at the Onset of
the COVID-19 Crisis,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity.
2. For further analysis of the ADP employment series, see
Tomaz Cajner, Leland D. Crane, Ryan A. Decker, John Grigsby,
Adrian Hamins-Puertolas, Erik Hurst, Christopher Kurz, and
Ahu Yildirmaz (forthcoming), “The U.S. Labor Market during
the Beginning of the Pandemic Recession,Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity. Note that the ADP employment series
referenced in this discussion differ from the ADP National
Employment Report, which is published monthly by the ADP
Research Institute in close collaboration with Moody’s Analytics.
The unprecedented magnitude, speed, and nature
of the COVID-19 shock to the economy rendered
traditional statistics insuf cient for monitoring
economic activity in a timely manner. As a result,
policymakers around the world turned to nontraditional
indicators of activity, both those based on private-
sector “big data” and those newly developed by of cial
statistical agencies. Because some of the most salient
characteristics of these indicators are their timeliness
and the time span they cover (such as daily or weekly),
they are often called “high-frequency indicators.
An important example of the usefulness of high-
frequency indicators is the case of payroll employment.
The Bureau of Labor Statistics’ (BLS) monthly measure
of payroll employment is one of the most reliable,
timely, and closely watched business cycle indicators.
However, during the onset of the pandemic in the
United States, even the BLS Current Employment
Statistics (CES) data were published with too long of
a lag to track the dramatic dislocations in the labor
market in a timely manner. Speci cally, from the
second half of March through early April, the economy
was shedding jobs at an unprecedented rate, but
those employment losses were captured only in the
employment situation release issued on May8, 2020.
Because of this lag, economists looked to various
private data sources to gain insights about the current
(continued on next page)
Monitoring Economic Activity with Nontraditional
High-Frequency Indicators
8 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
B. Indicators of consumption growth
Services spending Retail goods spending
Total, Census
30
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
30
Percent change from year earlier
Feb. Apr. June Aug. Oct. Dec. Feb.
2020 2021
Total, NPD
N
OTE
: NPD data are weekly and extend through February 6, 2021,
and Census data are monthly. All series show nominal spending on
nonfood retail goods. Dashed lines represent the rst and second waves
of stimulus tranche.
S
OURCE
: NPD Group; Census Bureau.
Airport passengers
Food services
Hotel occupancy
100
80
60
40
20
+
_
0
20
40
Year-over-year percent change
Feb. Apr. June Aug. Oct. Dec. Feb.
2020 2021
Daily
Health-care visits
N
OTE: Year-over-year percent change in 7-day moving average.
Health-care visits data extend through February 7, 2021; food services
data extend through February 15, 2021; and hotel occupancy data extend
through February 6, 2021.
S
OURCE: SafeGraph, Inc.; Fiserv, Inc.; STR, Inc.; Transportation
Security Administration.
Monitoring Economic Activity (continued)
analytics  rm) on nonfood retail sales captured in real
time the dramatic and sudden drop in consumption in
mid-March; the monthly Census Bureau data recorded
that decline only with a lag ( gure B, left panel).
3
The NPD data also re ected how the income support
payments to families, provided by the Coronavirus Aid,
Relief, and Economic Security Act, or CARES Act,
rapidly affected consumer spending in mid-April.
More recently, the NPD data showed some decline
in consumption late last year, followed by a pickup
in January after the passage of the most recent  scal
stimulus package. Several nontraditional data sources
illustrate that services spending remains depressed as
social distancing continues to restrain in-person activity
( gure B, right panel).
4
With rapid changes in the economic environment,
many statistical agencies also developed high-frequency
3. Information from the NPD Group, Inc., and its af liates
contained in this report is the proprietary and con dential
property of NPD and was made available for publication
under a limited license from NPD. Such information may not
be republished in any manner, in whole or in part, without the
express written consent of NPD.
4. Services spending accounts for roughly one-half of
aggregate spending, but it is measured with some lag. In
particular, the services spending information folded into
gross domestic product comes from the revenue information
sourced from the Census Bureau’s Quarterly Services Survey
(QSS). The advance QSS (early data for a subset of industries
found in the full QSS) and full QSS are released two and three
months, respectively, after a given quarter ends.
Weekly employment estimates based on ADP data
were particularly valuable not only last spring when
employment plummeted and then quickly rebounded,
but also during the renewed COVID-19 wave that
started this past fall. In particular, high-frequency ADP
employment data indicate that the fall and winter virus
wave had a smaller effect on the labor market than
was seen last spring, likely because there were fewer
mandated shutdowns of businesses than in the spring,
because many businesses implemented adaptations
that made it easier for them to continue to operate
(for example, curbside pickup), and because many
individuals changed their behavior (for example, by
wearing masks such that more economic activities are
deemed safer now than in the spring). Most recently,
the BLS data show that private payroll employment
remained little changed through its survey week in
mid-January, and the ADP data indicate that
employment improved modestly through early
February. Additionally, the latest ADP data indicate
that the leisure and hospitality sector—which includes
hotels, restaurants, and entertainment venues and
is particularly affected by government-mandated
restrictions and social distancing—started adding jobs
again in recent weeks after experiencing a temporary
downturn at the end of last year ( gure A, right panel).
Outside of the labor market, several new high-
frequency indicators have been useful in monitoring
the massive effects of the COVID-19 pandemic on
consumer spending. Weekly data from NPD (a market
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 9
C. High-frequency indicators by ocial statistical agencies
New business applications Houshold expectations
Cumulative 2020
Cumulative
2021
+
_
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
Thousands
Feb. Apr. June Aug. Oct. Dec.
Weekly
Cumulative
2017-19 average
N
OTE
: The cumulative 2021 data extend through February 6, 2021.
The data are derived from Employer Identication Number applications
with planned wages.
S
OURCE
: Business Formation Statistics, Census Bureau via Haver
Analytics.
High condence
in making
next mortgage
payment
Expect loss of
employment
income in
next 4 weeks
20
30
40
50
60
70
Percent of households
May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb.
2020 2021
Weekly
High condence
in making
next rent
payment
N
OTE
: Data extend through February 1, 2021. Dashed lines represent
pauses in Household Pulse Survey data collection.
S
OURCE
: Household Pulse Survey, Census Bureau via Haver
Analytics.
nancial struggles of households ( gure C, right
panel). These data indicate that the  nancial stress of
households increased late last year as households were
becoming less con dent about being able to make their
next mortgage or rent payment as well as more likely
to expect income loss over the next four weeks, but
households’  nancial expectations improved somewhat
in January.
Overall, nontraditional high-frequency indicators
have served several purposes over the past year.
First, they provide timely alternative estimates that
complement of cial statistics and can also be used to
verify movements in of cial statistics. Second, they are
often helpful for assessing economic developments
more quickly and with greater granularity than what
can be found in of cial statistics. Third, high-frequency
indicators without a direct counterpart in of cial
statistics give a different perspective and help enhance
our understanding of economic developments. These
nontraditional indicators are also subject to several
potential limitations, such as systematic biases due to
nonrepresentativeness of data or small (and possibly
nonrandom) samples. Importantly, only time will tell if
such indicators will continue to provide a signal above
and beyond traditional indicators as the high-frequency
shocks associated with the pandemic dissipate. Overall,
however, the use of nontraditional high-frequency
indicators over the past year has amply shown that they
can yield large bene ts, especially when economic
conditions are changing rapidly.
indicators. For example, the Census Bureau released
data on weekly new business applications ( gure C,
left panel). During the initial stage of the pandemic
recession, new business applications fell compared
with previous years, a typical pattern during economic
downturns. However, new business applications started
to rebound notably during the summer, and for the year
as a whole, they were higher than the average over the
previous three years, a pattern that differs dramatically
from previous business cycles.
5
The increase in
applications appears to be concentrated in industries
that rapidly adapted to the landscape of the pandemic,
such as online retail, personal services, information
technology, and delivery. It remains unclear, however,
whether these business applications will lead to actual
job creation at the same rate as in the past.
6
As another
example, the Census Bureau developed high-frequency
survey statistics that contain information about the
5. For further discussion, see Emin Dinlersoz, Timothy
Dunne, John Haltiwanger, and Veronika Penciakova
(forthcoming), “Business Formation: A Tale of Two Recessions,
American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings.
6. The link between applications and job creation in the
pre-pandemic period is studied in Kimberly Bayard, Emin
Dinlersoz, Timothy Dunne, John Haltiwanger, Javier Miranda,
and John Stevens (2018), “Early-Stage Business Formation:
An Analysis of Applications for Employer Identi cation
Numbers,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2018-
015 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, March), https://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2018.015.
10 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
in the employment-to-population ratio
were particularly evident among those
groups (gure4). (For more discussion
of the pandemic’s eects on the labor
market outcomes of various groups, see
the box “Disparities in Job Loss during the
Pandemic.”)
Aggregate wage growth appears to be
little changed despite the weakness in the
labor market
Although weakness in the labor market
generally puts downward pressure on overall
wages, the best available measures suggest
that wage growth in 2020 was little changed
from 2019. Total hourly compensation as
measured by the employment cost index,
which includes both wages and benets, rose
2.6percent during the 12 months ending in
December, only slightly below pre-pandemic
rates (gure5). Wage growth as computed by
the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, which
tracks the median 12-month wage growth
of individuals responding to the Current
Population Survey, was about 3½percent
Average hourly earnings,
private sector
Employment
cost index,
private sector
Atlanta Fed’s
Wage Growth Tracker
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
10
Percent change from year earlier
202120192017201520132011200920072005
Compensation per hour,
business sector
N
OTE: Business-sector compensation is on a 4-quarter percent chang
For the private-sector employment cost index, change is over
months ending in the last month of each quarter; for p
hourly earnings, the data are 12-month percent changes a
in March 2007; for the Atlanta Fed’s Wage Growth Tracker,
are shown as a 3-month moving average of the 12-month
SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Hispanic or Latino
Black or African American
Asian
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Percent
202120192017201520132011200920072005
4. Unemployment rate, by race and ethnicity
Monthly
White
N
OTE:Unemployment rate measures total unemployed as a percentage of the labor force. Persons whose ethnicity is identied as Hispanic or L
atino
may be of any race. Small sample sizes preclude reliable estimates for Native Americans and other groups for which monthly data are not reported
by
the Bureau of Labor Statistics.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 11
during 2020, similar to the growth rate
in 2019.
3
The continued gains in aggregate
wages mask important heterogeneity,
however; according to the Atlanta Fed data,
workers with lower earnings and nonwhites
experienced larger decelerations in wages than
other groups last year.
Price ination remains low despite
rebounding since last spring
As measured by the 12-month change in
the price index for personal consumption
expenditures (PCE), ination fell from
1.6percent in December2019 to a low of
0.5percent in April, as economic activity
dropped sharply (gure6). Since then,
ination has partially recovered along with the
pickup in demand, but it was only 1.3percent
in December—still well below the Federal
Open Market Committee’s (FOMC) objective
of 2percent. After excluding consumer food
and energy prices, which are often quite
volatile, the 12-month measure of core PCE
ination was 1.5percent in December. An
alternative way to abstract from transitory
inuences on measured ination is provided
by the trimmed mean measure of PCE price
ination constructed by the Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas.
4
The 12-month change in this
measure declined to 1.7percent in December
3. Some other common wage measures are providing
misleading signals at present because they are dominated
by compositional eects: Pandemic-related job losses fell
most heavily on lower-wage workers, which mechanically
increased measures of average wages. For example,
average hourly earnings from the payroll survey rose
more than 5 percent over the 12 months ending in
January. Similarly, the fourth-quarter reading on
compensation per hour, which includes both wages and
benets, was 7.7percent above its year-ago level. Output
per hour, or productivity, has also been aected by the
same composition eects, rising 2.5percent over the four
quarters of 2020, the fastest pace in a decade.
4. The trimmed mean price index excludes whichever
prices showed the largest increases or decreases in a given
month. Over the past 20years, changes in the trimmed
mean index have averaged ¼percentage point above core
PCE ination and 0.1percentage point above total PCE
ination.
Trimmed mean
Excluding food
and energy
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
12-month percent change
2020201920182017201620152014
6. Change in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures
Monthly
Total
NOTE: The data extend through December 2020.
S
OURCE: For trimmed mean, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas; for a
ll
else, Bureau of Economic Analysis; all via Haver Analytics.
12 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
distancing measures and relatively few workers are able
to work from home.
2
In keeping with the sectoral composition of recent
job losses, workers in lower-wage jobs have been hit
especially hard. Figure B uses data from the payroll
processor ADP to plot employment indexes for four
job tiers de ned by hourly wages. Between February
and April of last year, employment fell most sharply for
jobs in the bottom quartile of the pre-pandemic wage
distribution. Between April and June, employment
rose most quickly for these lowest-paying jobs. In
subsequent months, job gains moderated substantially
for all groups, and as of mid-January, employment in
the lowest-paying jobs was about 20percent below its
2. For instance, in the January2021 round of the Current
Population Survey, 41percent of those employed in the
professional and business services industry reported working
from home during the previous four weeks as a result of the
pandemic, compared with about 7percent of those employed
in leisure and hospitality. See Bureau of Labor Statistics (2021),
“Supplemental Data Measuring the Effects of the Coronavirus
(COVID-19) Pandemic on the Labor Market,” Current
Population Survey, January, https://www.bls.gov/cps/effects-of-
the-coronavirus-covid-19-pandemic.htm.
A. Changes in private-sector employment, by industry
Industry
Percent change since Feb. 2020
(1)
As of Apr. 2020
(2)
As of Jan. 2021
1. Total private ........................... −16.5 −6.6
2. Mining and logging ............... 9.9 −11.7
3. Manufacturing ....................... −10.8 −4.5
4. Construction .......................... −14.6 −3.3
5. Wholesale trade ..................... −6.9 −4.5
6. Retail trade ............................. −15.2 −2.5
7. Transp., warehousing, and
utilities ....................................
9.1 −2.7
8. Information and  nancial
activities ..................................
−4.8 −2.8
9. Professional and business
services ....................................
−11.1 −3.8
10. Education and health
services ....................................
−11.6 −5.4
11. Leisure and hospitality ......... −48.6 −22.9
12. Other services ........................ −23.7 −7.8
N: The data are seasonally adjusted.
S: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Although employment has improved substantially
since its trough in April2020, the labor market
recovery remains far from complete: As of
January2021, the employment-to-population (EPOP)
ratio, a broad measure that encompasses both
increased unemployment and decreased labor force
participation, was still 3.6percentage points below
its February2020 level. All industries, occupations,
and demographic groups experienced signi cant
employment declines at the start of the pandemic,
and, over the ensuing months, all groups have
experienced at least some partial recovery. That
said, employment declines last spring were steeper
for workers with lower earnings and for Hispanics,
African Americans, and other minority groups, and
the hardest-hit groups still have the most ground left
to regain.
Although disparities in labor market outcomes
generally widen during recessions, certain
factors unique to this episode—in particular, the
social-distancing measures taken by households,
businesses, and governments to limit in-person
interactions—have profoundly shaped the incidence
of recent job losses in different segments of the labor
market. Because jobs differ in the degree to which
they involve personal contact and physical proximity,
in whether they can be performed remotely, and in
whether they are deemed to serve “essential” functions,
social-distancing measures have had disparate effects
across industries and occupations. To illustrate this
point, gure A reports net changes in employment in
11 broad industry categories, both during the period
of acute job losses last spring (column 1) and over the
longer interval since the start of the pandemic (column
2). Net job losses through January have been especially
severe in the leisure and hospitality industry—in which
employment is still 22.9percent below pre-pandemic
levels (line 11)—and in other services, a category that
includes barber shops and beauty salons (line 12).
1
By
contrast, employment in most other broad industries is
now 5percent or less below pre-pandemic levels. Job
losses have thus been disproportionately concentrated
in lower-wage consumer service industries, in which
business operations are strongly affected by social-
1. Net job losses have also been pronounced in mining
and logging (line 2), which is unique among these industries
in having experienced further contraction in employment
between April2020 and January2021.
Disparities in Job Loss during the Pandemic
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 13
pre-pandemic level. In comparison, employment in the
higher-paying job tiers is now about 10percent or less
below pre-pandemic levels.
Similar disparities are apparent across demographic
groups. Figure C shows the change in each group’s
EPOP ratio. Between February2020 and January2021,
the EPOP ratio fell by a similar amount for both men
and women; in contrast, during many previous
recessions the EPOP ratio declined substantially more
for men. (In fact, given that men’s employment rate was
substantially higher than women’s before the pandemic,
the decline in employment for women as a percentage
of pre-recession employment has been larger, which
contrasts even more starkly with previous recessions.)
Since February2020, the EPOP ratio has fallen more
for people without a bachelor’s degree than for those
with at least a bachelor’s degree, more for prime-age
individuals than for those under age 25 or over age 55,
and more for Hispanics, African Americans, and Asians
than for whites.
3
In general, the groups experiencing the
largest declines in employment since last February are
more commonly employed in the industries that have
3. The decline in employment also appears to have been
relatively large for Native Americans, based on annual average
data for 2020. (Monthly data are not available for this group
because of small sample sizes and are not shown in  gure C
for that reason.)
experienced the greatest net employment declines to
date, such as leisure and hospitality; these demographic
groups are also less likely to report being able to work
from home.
4
4. For more information on the groups with the largest
employment declines since February2020, see Kenneth
A. Couch, Robert W. Fairlie, and Huanan Xu (2020),
“Early Evidence of the Impacts of COVID-19 on Minority
Unemployment,Journal of Public Economics, vol. 192
(December), pp. 1–11; Guido Matias Cortes and Eliza C.
Forsythe (2020), “The Heterogeneous Labor Market Impacts
of the Covid-19 Pandemic,” Upjohn Institute Working Paper
Series 20-327 (Kalamazoo, Mich.: W.E. Upjohn Institute for
Employment Research, May), https://research.upjohn.org/cgi/
viewcontent.cgi?article=1346&context=up_workingpapers;
and Titan Alon, Matthias Doepke, Jane Olmstead-Rumsey, and
Michèle Tertilt (2020), “This Time It’s Different: The Role of
Women’s Employment in a Pandemic Recession,” NBER Working
Paper 27660 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research, August), https://www.nber.org/papers/w27660.
Additional details on differences across demographic
groups in the ability to work from home can be found in the
Current Population Survey. For example, in January, around
23percent of white workers reported working from home in the
previous four weeks because of the pandemic, compared with
19percent of African Americans and 14percent of Hispanics;
43percent of those with a bachelor’s degree or higher reported
working from home, compared with 16percent or less for those
with lower levels of education. See Bureau of Labor Statistics,
“Supplemental Data,” in box note 2.
-20 -15 -10 -5 0
C. Change in employment-to-population ratio, by
demographic group
Percentage points
Feb. 2020 to Jan. 2021Feb. to Apr. 2020
Hispanic or Latino
Asian
Black or African American
White
55+
25–54
16–24
Bachelor’s degree and higher
Some college or associate’s degree
High school graduates, no college
Less than a high school diploma
Women
Men
N
OTE: The data are seasonally adjusted. Small sample sizes preclude
reliable estimates for Native Americans and other groups for which
monthly data are not reported by the Bureau of Labor Statistics.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
Bottom
Top
Top-middle
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
Week ending February 15, 2020 = 100
Mar. May July Sept. Nov. Jan.
2020 2021
B. Employment declines for low-, middle-, and
high-wage workers
Weekly
Bottom-
middle
N
OTE: The data are seasonally adjusted by the Federal Reserve Board
and extend through January 16, 2021. Wage quartiles are dened using
the February 2020 wage distribution.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board sta calculations using ADP, Inc.,
payroll processing data.
(continued on next page)
14 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
be important for narrowing the disparities that have
widened since the start of the pandemic, as research
has consistently shown that strong labor markets
especially bene t lower-wage and disadvantaged
workers.
7
The pace of labor market gains will also
depend on how many unemployed workers have
the opportunity to return to their original jobs. In
January2021, 2.2percent of labor force participants
(representing 34.6percent of unemployed workers)
reported being unemployed because of a permanent
job loss, up from 1.3percent of the labor force
(8.8percent of unemployed workers) in April2020.
8
Research has shown that workers who return to their
previous employers after a temporary layoff tend to earn
wages similar to what they were making previously,
whereas laid-off workers who do not return to their
previous employer experience a longer-lasting decline
in earnings.
9
7. For example, see Stephanie R. Aaronson, Mary C. Daly,
William L. Wascher, and David W. Wilcox (2019), “Okun
Revisited: Who Bene ts Most from a Strong Economy?”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, pp. 333–75,
https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2019/03/
aaronson_web.pdf; and Tomaz Cajner, Tyler Radler, David
Ratner, and Ivan Vidangos (2017), “Racial Gaps in Labor
Market Outcomes in the Last Four Decades and over
the Business Cycle,” Finance and Economics Discussion
Series 2017-071 (Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, June), https://dx.doi.org/10.17016/
FEDS.2017.071.
8. The data are Federal Reserve Board staff calculations
from published Bureau of Labor Statistics estimates. By
comparison, the number of permanent job losers peaked
at 4.4percent of labor force participants (representing
44.8percent of unemployed workers) during the Great Recession.
9. See Louis S. Jacobson, Robert J. LaLonde, and Daniel G.
Sullivan (1993), “Earnings Losses of Displaced Workers,
American Economic Review, vol. 83 (September), pp. 685–
709; Shigeru Fujita and Giuseppe Moscarini (2017), “Recall
and Unemployment,American Economic Review, vol. 107
(December), pp. 3875–916; and Marta Lachowska, Alexandre
Mas, and Stephen A. Woodbury (2020), “Sources of Displaced
Workers’ Long-Term Earnings Losses,” American Economic
Review, vol. 110 (October), pp. 3231–66.
Since the start of the pandemic, another important
impediment to individuals’ ability to work or look for
work has been the absence of in-person education for
many K–12 students.
5
Because many working parents
are unable to work from home while monitoring their
children’s virtual education (depending on the nature
of their jobs and the availability of other caregivers),
the widespread lack of K–12 in-person education may
also explain some of the differences across groups.
For example, among mothers aged 25 to 54 with
children aged 6 to 17, the fraction who said they are
not working or looking for work for caregiving reasons
was 2½percentage points higher in the three months
ending January 2021 than over the year-earlier period,
compared with a ½ percentage point increase for
fathers. Relative to white mothers, the increase was
about twice as large for Hispanic mothers and more
than twice as large for African American mothers, and it
was also more than twice as large for mothers without
any college education as for mothers with more
education.
6
As the spread of COVID-19 is contained and
a growing share of the population is immunized,
some of the unique factors that have exacerbated
disparities since the start of the pandemic will likely
ease. For example, as COVID becomes less prevalent,
businesses offering in-person services (for example, in
the leisure and hospitality industry) will move closer
to pre-pandemic levels of employment. In addition, as
more schools return to offering in-person education,
childcare constraints will become less acute.
Even as labor market impediments speci c to the
pandemic subside, however, the speed at which the
labor market moves toward full employment will
5. According to the Census Bureau’s Household Pulse
Survey, 85percent of parents surveyed in early January
reported that their children’s classes for the 2020–21 school
year were moved to virtual learning.
6. The  ndings are Federal Reserve Board staff estimates
based on publicly available Current Population Survey microdata.
Disparities in Job Loss (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 15
from 2percent a year earlier, a similar decrease
to those in total and core PCE ination.
The low level of consumer price ination
in 2020 partly reected the deterioration in
economic activity. For example, ination in
tenants’ rent and owners’ equivalent rent,
which tend to be sensitive to overall economic
conditions, softened in 2020 from the rates
observed during the preceding few years.
Low ination also reected the net eect
of a number of pandemic-driven shifts in
specic sectors of the economy, such as a
decline in gasoline prices that resulted from
a collapse in oil prices in the early part of
the year, which only partially reversed in the
second half. Similarly, airfares and hotel prices
fell markedly, driven by huge reductions in
demand due to the pandemic. In contrast,
food prices increased at an unusually fast
pace last year, given stronger demand at retail
grocery stores and, at times, some pandemic-
related supply chain disruptions. In addition,
prices for some durable goods, such as motor
vehicles and home appliances, rose sharply
during the summer and remained somewhat
elevated at the end of the year, in part because
of a pandemic-induced shift in demand away
from services and toward these goods.
Prices of imports and oil have also
rebounded
The partial rebound in ination later in 2020
also stemmed from a rming of import prices.
After declining in the rst half of last year,
nonfuel import prices increased in the second
half, as the dollar depreciated and the recovery
in global demand put upward pressure on
non-oil commodity prices—a substantial
component of nonfuel import prices (gure7).
Prices of both agricultural commodities and
industrial metals increased considerably, and
nonfuel import prices are now higher than
they were a year ago.
Early in the pandemic, benchmark oil prices
fell below $20 per barrel, a level not breached
since 2002. While prices have now nearly
Nonfuel import prices
92
94
96
98
100
102
104
January 2014 = 100
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
20212020201920182017201620152014
7. Nonfuel import prices and industrial metals indexes
January 2014 = 100
Industrial metals
N
OTE: The data for nonfuel import prices are monthly and extend through
December 2020. The data for industrial metals are monthly averages of daily
data and extend through January 29, 2021.
S
OURCE: For nonfuel import prices, Bureau of Labor Statistics; for industrial
metals, S&P GSCI Industrial Metals Spot Index via Haver Analytics.
16 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
recovered, oil consumption and production are
still well below pre-pandemic levels (gure8).
Although global economic activity has picked
up since last spring, oil demand has not fully
recovered, held back by the slow recovery in
travel and commuting. Weak demand has been
met by reductions in supply: U.S. production
has fallen dramatically relative to a year ago,
while OPEC (Organization of the Petroleum
Exporting Countries) and Russia have only
slightly increased production after making
sharp cuts last spring.
Survey-based measures of long-run
ination expectations have been
broadly stable . . .
Despite the volatility in actual ination last
year, survey-based measures of ination
expectations at medium- and longer-term
horizons, which likely inuence actual ination
by aecting wage- and price-setting decisions,
have been little changed on net (gure9).
In the University of Michigan Surveys of
Consumers, the median value for ination
expectations over the next 5 to 10years was
2.7percent in January and early February.
In the Survey of Consumer Expectations,
conducted by the Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, the median of respondents’
expected ination rate three years ahead was
3.0percent in January, somewhat above its
year-earlier level. Finally, in the rst-quarter
Survey of Professional Forecasters, conducted
by the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
the median expectation for the annual rate
of increase in the PCE price index over the
next 10years was 2.0percent, close to the
level around which it had typically hovered in
previous years.
. . . and market-based measures of
ination compensation have retraced
earlier declines
Ination expectations can also be inferred
from market-based measures of ination
compensation, although the inference is
not straightforward because these measures
are aected by changes in premiums that
provide compensation for bearing ination
Michigan survey,
next 5 to 10 years
NY Fed survey,
3 years ahead
1
2
3
4
Percent
202120192017201520132011200920072005
Survey of Professional
Forecasters,
next 10 years
9. Surveys of ination expectations
NOTE: The series are medians of the survey responses. The Michigan
survey data are monthly and extend through February 2021; the
February data are preliminary. The Survey of Professional Forecasters
data for ination expectations for personal consumption expenditures
are quarterly, begin in 2007:Q1, and extend through 2021:Q1. The N
Y
Fed survey data are monthly and begin in June 2013.
SOURCE: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, Survey of Consumer Expectations; Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Survey of Professional Forecasters.
Brent spot price
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
160
Dollars per barrel
2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021
8. Spot and futures prices for crude oil
Weekly
24-month-ahead
futures contracts
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily data. The data begin on
Thursdays and extend through February 10, 2021.
S
OURCE
: ICE Brent Futures via Bloomberg.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 17
and liquidity risks. Measures of longer-term
ination compensation—derived either from
dierences between yields on nominal Treasury
securities and those on comparable-maturity
Treasury Ination-Protected Securities (TIPS),
or from ination swaps—dropped sharply
last March, partly reecting a reduction in
the relative liquidity of TIPS compared with
nominal Treasury securities (gure10). Both
measures rebounded in the next couple of
months as liquidity improved, before drifting
up further through the remainder of 2020 and
early 2021. The TIPS-based measure of 5-to-
10-year-forward ination compensation and
the analogous measure from ination swaps
are now about 2¼ percent and 2½ percent,
respectively, a bit above the average levels seen
in 2019.
5
The plunge and rebound in gross
domestic product reected unusual
patterns of spending during the pandemic
After contracting with unprecedented speed
and severity in the rst half of 2020, gross
domestic product (GDP) rose rapidly in the
third quarter and continued to pick up, albeit
at a much slower pace, in the fourth quarter
(gure11). The rebound in activity reected a
relaxation of voluntary and mandatory social
distancing, as well as unprecedented scal and
monetary support. Nevertheless, the recovery
remains incomplete: At the end of 2020, GDP
was 2.5percent below its level four quarters
earlier. This incomplete recovery reected
weakness in services consumption and overall
exports that resulted largely from ongoing
social-distancing measures to contain the virus,
both at home and abroad. The concentration
of the recession in services is unprecedented in
the United States. Indeed, the sectors that are
typically responsible for the cyclical dynamics
of GDP have shown remarkable resilience:
Activity in the housing market and consumer
spending on goods were both above their
5. As these measures are based on consumer price
index (CPI) ination, one should probably subtract about
¼percentage point—the average dierential between CPI
and PCE ination over the past two decades—to infer
ination compensation on a PCE basis.
Ination swaps
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
Percent
20212019201720152013
10. 5-to-10-year-forward ination compensation
Weekly
TIPS breakeven rates
N
OTE
:The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend throug
h
February 12, 2021. TIPS is Treasury Ination-Protected Securities.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Barclays; Federal R
eserve
Board sta estimates.
Gross domestic product
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
Billions of chained 2012 dollars
20202018201620142012201020082006
11. Real gross domestic product and gross
domestic income
Quarterly
Gross domestic income
N
OTE: Gross domestic income extends through 2020:Q3.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
18 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
pre-pandemic levels in the fourth quarter, and
business xed investment and manufacturing
output also recovered rapidly from their
initial plunges.
Consumer spending, particularly on
goods, bounced back in the second half
of 2020 . . .
Household consumption rebounded rapidly
during the late spring and summer from its
COVID-induced plunge, and it continued to
make gains through the fourth quarter, ending
the year 2.6percent below its year-earlier
level. Notably, purchases of both durable
and nondurable goods rose above their pre-
COVID levels in the second half of 2020, as
spending shifted away from services curtailed
by voluntary and mandatory social distancing
(gure12). Within durable goods, sales of light
motor vehicles moved up quickly in the second
half and are now close to their pre-pandemic
level; any residual weakness in sales may be
attributable to low supply, as production
has failed to keep pace with demand.
Services spending also rebounded from the
extraordinarily low level seen in April, but
it remained well below its pre-pandemic
pace through the fourth quarter, as concerns
about the virus continued to limit in-person
interactions. Notably, consumer sentiment has
also remained well below pre-pandemic levels
(gure13).
. . . assisted by government income
support . . .
Consumer spending has been bolstered by
government income support in the form
of unemployment insurance and stimulus
measures targeted at households. These
payments were largest in the spring and
summer of last year, but even in the fourth
quarter aggregate real disposable personal
income (DPI) was 3.7percent above the level
prevailing in late 2019, despite the low level of
employment.
6
The still-elevated level of DPI,
6. The Consolidated Appropriations Act, 2021,
which was enacted in late December, should provide a
Michigan survey
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
1966 = 100
10
30
50
70
90
110
130
150
170
202120182015201220092006
1985 = 100
13. Indexes of consumer sentiment
Conference Board
N
OTE: The data are monthly. Michigan survey data extend through
February 2021; the February data are preliminary.
S
OURCE: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; Conference
Board.
Goods
6.5
7.0
7.5
8.0
8.5
9.0
9.5
Billions of chained 2012 dollars
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
202020172014201120082005
12. Real personal consumption expenditures
Billions of chained 2012 dollars
Services
N
OTE: The data are monthly and extend through December 2020.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 19
combined with the low level of consumption,
resulted in an aggregate saving rate of more
than 13percent in the fourth quarter, nearly
double its level from a year earlier (gure14).
7
That said, these aggregate gures mask
important variation across households, and
many low-income households, especially
those whose earnings declined as a result of
the pandemic and recession, have seen their
nances stretched.
8
. . . but spending fell back late in the year
As COVID cases began rising again
in November, some states retightened
restrictions, and many households likely cut
back voluntarily on their activities, leading
to a retrenchment in spending on services
such as restaurants and travel. Spending
on durable goods also stepped down late in
the fourth quarter, possibly in part because
many households had already purchased
durable items such as furniture and electronics
earlier in the year. Further, while higher-
income households accrued substantial
savings over the course of 2020, some lower-
income consumers likely began to reduce
their spending toward the end of the year,
as support provided by the Coronavirus
Aid, Relief, and Economic Security Act
(CARES Act) waned. More recently,
however, retail sales data and high-frequency
indicators suggest that consumer spending
substantial further boost to DPI in the rst quarter of
this year.
7. The saving rate reached 26percent in the second
quarter of 2020—by far the highest level since World
War II—before falling back as consumption rebounded
and government transfers declined over the course of
the year. Even so, the saving rate in the fourth quarter
remained higher than in any other period since the 1970s.
8. Food pantries saw a signicant increase in demand
in 2020, and there was a sharp increase in the number of
families reporting that they did not have sucient money
to buy food. See, for example, Marianne Bitler, Hilary
W. Hoynes, and Diane Whitmore Schanzenbach (2020),
“The Social Safety Net in the Wake of COVID-19,
NBER Working Paper Series 27796 (Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research, September),
https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/
w27796/w27796.pdf.
0
4
8
12
16
20
24
28
32
36
PercentMonthly
20202018201620142012201020082006
14. Personal saving rate
NOTE: The data extend through December 2020.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
20 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
rose appreciably in January, likely in part
because of additional scal support from the
Consolidated Appropriations Act, 2021, which
was enacted in late December.
Soaring equity and house prices have
pushed aggregate household wealth to
record highs
Stock markets rallied after plunging in the
spring and, more recently, have reached
record highs, largely reecting the arrival of
eective vaccines, optimism about further
scal stimulus, and notable improvement in
the outlook for corporate earnings. House
prices—which are of particular importance for
the value of assets held by many households—
have also soared, boosted by strong demand
from record-low mortgage rates, a shift in
demand from multifamily to single-family
homes during the pandemic, and a shortage
of inventory (gure15). As a result, aggregate
household wealth is elevated relative to income,
which is supporting consumption, particularly
of relatively well-o households
(gure16).
Lending standards for households are
less accommodative than before the
pandemic, but credit is still available to
households with good credit proles
Consumer lending standards remain less
accommodative than before the pandemic,
on balance, and are particularly tight for
individuals with low credit ratings. Banks
tightened lending standards substantially in the
rst half of 2020, but the tightening moderated
in the second half and credit remains available
to higher-score borrowers. Banks also reported
considerably weaker demand for consumer
credit on balance. Credit card lending volumes
have been weak, consistent with the incomplete
recovery in overall consumer spending, but
auto lending has been stronger amid the rapid
recovery in motor vehicle sales to consumers
(gure17). Mortgage lending has also been
robust, boosted both by record-low mortgage
interest rates and by mortgage credit that is
generally available to those with good credit
scores who are seeking traditional mortgage
30
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
Billions of dollars, monthly rate
2020201820162014201220102008
17. Consumer credit ows
H1
Q3
NOTE:
The data are seasonally adjusted by the Federal Reserve Board.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release G.19,Consumer
Credit.”
Student loans
Auto loans
Credit cards
S&P/Case-Shiller
national index
CoreLogic
price index
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
2005 = 100
20202018201620142012201020082006
15. Real prices of existing single-family houses
Quarterly
Zillow index
N
OTE
: The data for the S&P/Case-Shiller index extend through
2020:Q3. Series are deated by the personal consumption expenditure
price index.
S
OURCE
: CoreLogic Home Price Index; Zillow; S&P/Case-Shiller U.S.
National Home Price Index. The S&P/Case-Shiller index is a product o
f
S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC and/or its aliates. (For Dow Jones
Indices licensing information, see the note on the Contents page.)
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
7.0
7.5
Ratio
20202017201420112008200520021999
16. Wealth-to-income ratio
Quarterly
NOTE: The series is the ratio of household net worth to disposable
personal income. Data extend through 2020:Q3.
S
OURCE: For net worth, Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release
Z.1, “Financial Accounts of the United States”; for income, Bureau of
Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 21
products (gure18). Overall, loan defaults
have remained low despite the weak labor
market, supported by various forbearance
programs.
The housing sector made a remarkable
recovery in the second half of 2020 . . .
Residential investment grew at a robust
pace of 14percent over the four quarters
of2020, as booming home sales and housing
construction in the second half more than
oset the outsized declines in the second
quarter that resulted from the COVID-19
outbreak and mitigation eorts. Historically
low mortgage rates and the swift adaptation
of the real estate sector to the pandemic
boosted housing activity later in the year,
with both single-family housing starts and
existing home sales rising to their highest levels
since the mid-2000s (gures 19 and20).
9
The
burst of housing demand has left inventories
of both new and existing homes at all-time
lows, putting upward pressure on home
prices and supporting new construction.
Some of these patterns in the data likely
reect changes in preferences during the
pandemic, with households opting for larger
homes and housing in less dense areas, but
the degree to which these changes will persist
remains unclear.
. . . and business xed investment also
rebounded rapidly . . .
Business xed investment—that is, private
expenditures for equipment, structures,
research and development, and other
intellectual property—contracted sharply
in the rst half of 2020 but largely retraced
its decline in the second half. The recovery
in business investment has been centered in
equipment and intellectual property, which
rose 2.4percent over the four quarters of 2020,
supported by stronger business sentiment,
improved nancing conditions, and the
9. In particular, during the pandemic, the real estate
sector has made increased use of virtual tours, remote
closings, and waivers on inspections and appraisals.
2
3
4
5
6
Percent
202120192017201520132011
18. Mortgage rates
Weekly
NOTE: The data extend through February 11, 2021.
SOURCE: Freddie Mac Primary Mortgage Market Survey.
Single-family
permits
Multifamily starts
0
.2
.4
.6
.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
2.0
Millions of units, annual rate
20202018201620142012201020082006
19. Private housing starts and permits
Monthly
Single-family starts
N
OTE: The data extend through December 2020.
S
OURCE
: Census Bureau via Haver Analytics.
Existing home sales
.2
.4
.6
.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
Millions, annual rate
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
7.0
7.5
20202018201620142012201020082006
20. New and existing home sales
Millions, annual rate
New home sales
N
OTE:Data are monthly and extend through December 2020.
New
home sales include only single-family sales. Existing home sales include
single-family, condo, and co-op sales.
S
OURCE: For new home sales, Census Bureau; for existing home sales,
National Association of Realtors; all via Haver Analytics.
22 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
unwinding of direct disruptions from social
distancing (gure21). In addition, the health
crisis and the shift to widespread teleworking
have led to a surge in investment in both
medical equipment and computers. In contrast,
investment in nonresidential structures
continued to decline sharply in the second
half. Drilling investment was particularly
hard hit and fell 30percent in2020 as a result
of declines in energy demand and oil prices.
Investment in nondrilling structures also fell,
although more moderately. Long build times
imply that the decline in new construction
projects started in the rst half of 2020 led
to less ongoing spending in the second half;
moreover, rms likely remain uncertain about
future demand for many types of structures in
the wake of the pandemic.
. . . amid notable improvements in
corporate nancing conditions
Financing conditions for nonnancial rms
through capital markets have improved
notably since June. In particular, interest
rates have remained very low and corporate
bond spreads have narrowed. Gross issuance
of nonnancial corporate bonds was solid
in the second half of the year, although it
slowed from the exceptional pace in the second
quarter (gure22). In contrast, aggregate
bank lending to businesses contracted in the
second half, reecting lower demand for new
loans, the repayment of outsized draws on
credit lines earlier this year, the forgiveness
of some loans under the Paycheck Protection
Program, and tighter bank credit standards. In
part because of policy actions to foster smooth
market functioning, corporations have been
able to take advantage of favorable funding
conditions in capital markets to renance debt
and bolster their balance sheets; as a result,
corporate cash holdings are at record levels.
In the small business sector, privately nanced
lending also picked up over the summer, and
loan performance improved, supported by the
Paycheck Protection Program. Nevertheless,
80
40
+
_
0
40
80
120
160
200
Billions of dollars, monthly rate
2020201820162014201220102008
22. Selected components of net debt nancing for
nonnancial businesses
Sum
H1
H2
S
OURCE: Mergent Inc., Fixed Income Securities Database; S&P
Global, Leveraged Commentary & Data; DTCC Solutions LLC,
an
aliate of The Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation. This
publication includes data licensed from DTCC Solutions LLC,
an
aliate of The Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation. (For the
DTCC licensing disclaimer, see the note on the Contents page.)
Commercial paper
Bonds
Bank loans
Structures
1,000
1,200
1,400
1,600
1,800
2,000
2,200
2,400
Billions of chained 2012 dollars
350
400
450
500
550
600
650
202020172014201120082005
21. Real business xed investment
Billions of chained 2012 dollars
Equipment and
intangible capital
N
OTE: Business xed investment is known asprivate nonresidential
xed investment” in the national income and product accounts. The data
are quarterly.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 23
credit availability for small businesses remains
fairly tight, demand for such credit is weak,
and default risk is still elevated.
Exports remain lower, but imports have
recovered
U.S. exports remain well below pre-pandemic
levels. With many foreign economies still weak,
U.S. exports of goods have not quite fully
recovered from their earlier sharp declines,
while exports of services remain depressed
because of the continued suspension of most
international travel. In contrast, imports have
regained most of their lost ground. Reduced
imports of services have been oset by a full
rebound of goods imports, which reects
strong U.S. demand for household goods
(gure23). Both the nominal trade decit
and current account decit, relative to GDP,
widened since 2019 (gure24).
Federal scal stimulus provided
substantial support to economic activity
while also signicantly boosting the
budget decit and debt
Federal scal policy measures enacted in
response to the pandemic continue to provide
crucial income support to households and
businesses, as well as grants-in-aid to state
and local governments. These measures
have also facilitated loans to businesses,
households, states, and localities.
10
In total,
the Congressional Budget Oce projects that
in scal years 2020 and 2021, the additional
federal government expenditures and foregone
revenues from these policies will total roughly
$3trillion—around 15percent of nominal
GDP.
11
In addition, the decline in economic
10. These policy measures include the CARES Act
from last spring and the Consolidated Appropriations
Act, 2021, enacted in December. Passage of additional
scal support remains under discussion.
11. The CBO’s projection and estimate can be found
at Congressional Budget Oce (2020), An Update to
the Budget Outlook: 2020 to 2030 (Washington: CBO,
September2), https://www.cbo.gov/publication/56517;
and Congressional Budget Oce and Joint Committee
Imports
1,500
1,750
2,000
2,250
2,500
2,750
3,000
3,250
3,500
3,750
Billions of chained 2012 dollars
2020201820162014201220102008
23. Real imports and exports of goods
and services
Quarterly
Exports
S
OURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Current account
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
+
_
0
Percent of nominal GDP
2020201820162014201220102008200620042002
24. U.S. trade and current account balances
Annual
Trade
N
OTE
: GDP is gross domestic product. The data for the trade balance
extend through 2020. The data for the current account balance
extend
through 2019. The blue dot refers to the average current account balance
for 2020:Q1–2020:Q3.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
24 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
activity has pushed down tax receipts while
pushing up outlays for certain transfer
programs—most notably for unemployment
insurance and Medicaid (gure25). These tax
decreases and transfer increases (referred to as
automatic stabilizers) worked in tandem with
the discretionary stimulus to support aggregate
demand and blunt the extent of the economic
downturn.
The combination of the discretionary stimulus
measures and the automatic stabilizers caused
the budget decit in scal 2020 to rise to
15percent of nominal GDP—the largest
decit as a share of GDP in the post–World
War II era—up from its already elevated level
of 4½percent in scal 2019. Consequently,
the ratio of federal debt held by the public to
nominal GDP rose from 79percent in scal
2019 to 100percent by the end of scal 2020,
the highest debt-to-GDP ratio since 1947
(gure26). Even so, the cost of servicing the
federal debt is not particularly elevated by
historical standards, because Treasury rates are
extremely low.
State and local governments are facing
challenging scal conditions
State and local governments are confronting
challenging budget conditions because of
weak tax collections and extraordinary
expenses related to the pandemic. Nominal
state government tax collections in 2020 were
about 1percent below their 2019 level and
well below levels generally expected before
the pandemic (gure27).
12
The magnitude of
on Taxation (2021), “H.R. 133, Summary Estimate for
Divisions M Through FF Consolidated Appropriations
Act, 2021 Public Law 116–260, cost estimate,
January14, https://www.cbo.gov/publication/56963.
12. State tax collection data are available through
November2020. For additional details, see Urban
Institute (2020), “State Tax and Economic Review,
State and Local Finance Initiative, November, https://
www.urban.org/policy-centers/cross-center-initiatives/
state-and-local-finance-initiative/projects/state-tax-and-
economic-review (accessed January 2021).
Although depressed, tax receipts have not fallen as
signicantly as economic activity, for several reasons.
First, some of the federal scal aid to households (for
Debt held by
the public
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
Percent of nominal GDP
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
26. Federal government debt and net interest outlays
Percent of nominal GDP
1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 2020
Net interest outlays
on federal debt
NOTE: The data for net interest outlays are annual, begin in 1948, and
extend through 2020. Net interest outlays are the cost of servicing the
debt held by the public. Federal debt held by the public equals federal
debt less Treasury securities held in federal employee dened-benet
retirement accounts, evaluated at the end of the quarter. The data for
federal debt begin in 1900 and are annual from 1900 to 1951 and
quarterly thereafter. The data for gross domestic product (GDP) and
federal debt extend through 2020:Q3.
S
OURCE: For GDP, Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver
Analytics; for federal debt, Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release
Z.1, “Financial Accounts of the United States.”
Expenditures
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
30
40
50
Percent change from year earlier
202120192017201520132011200920072005
Monthly
25. Federal receipts and expenditures
Receipts
N
OTE
: The data are 12-month moving sums.
S
OURCE
: Oce of Management and Budget via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 25
these revenue shortfalls varied considerably
across states, with the largest shortfalls in
states that rely heavily on sales taxes, tourism,
and energy production. In contrast, property
taxes—the principal local government
tax—have continued to rise apace, and
state and local governments have received
federal aid that has assisted with COVID-
related expenses and helped ease budget
strains. Meanwhile, bond market conditions
for state and local governments have been
generally accommodative in the second
half of the year, as robust municipal bond
issuance has been supported by historically
low yields and tax-exempt municipal bond
funds have seen solid inows. Even so, in
response to social-distancing restrictions
(including virtual learning), current budget
pressures, and concerns over future budgetary
challenges, state and local governments have
cut payrolls—particularly in the education
sector—an unprecedented 6½ percent over the
past year (gure28). Notably, public-sector
employment is down signicantly in nearly all
states, including those that have experienced
relatively smaller revenue shocks.
Vaccines offer hope of an end to the
pandemic, but risks to the outlook are
still substantial
The economic outlook presented in Part3
depends crucially on the course of the
COVID-19 pandemic. The vaccination
campaign now under way oers the prospect
of a return to more normal conditions
by the end of this year. But the pace of
vaccinations, the rate of decline in the spread
of the virus, and the speed with which people
return to normal activities all remain highly
uncertain, particularly given the emergence
of new, apparently more contagious strains.
The longer-run economic eects of the
pandemic are also dicult to predict. Many
example, unemployment benets) is taxable. Second,
goods consumption, which is likelier to be subject to
sales taxes than services, has largely held up. Finally,
unemployment has been concentrated among low-income
individuals, who pay less in income taxes.
18.0
18.5
19.0
19.5
20.0
Millions
202120182015201220092006
Monthly
28. State and local government payroll employment
NOTE: The data are seasonally adjusted.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics, National Compensation Survey.
Total state taxes
5
+
_
0
5
10
Year-over-year percent change
202020192018201720162015
27. State and local tax receipts
NOTE: State tax data are 12-month percent changes of 4-quarter
moving averages, extend through November 2020, and are aggregated
over all states except Wyoming, for which data are not available.
Revenues from Washington, DC, are also excluded. Data for October
and November are missing for New Mexico, as this state has longer
reporting lags than others. Property tax data are 4-quarter percent
changes of 4-quarter moving averages, extend through 2020:Q3, and are
primarily collected by local governments.
S
OURCE: State Tax and Economic Review Project; State and Local
Finance Initiative at Urban Institute; Census Bureau.
Property taxes
26 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
small businesses have shut down and may
not reopen. Some pandemic-driven shifts in
economic activity, such as from in-person
to online shopping and from oce-based to
remote work, may prove to be permanent.
These shifts could increase productivity by
substituting remote interactions for costly
travel and commuting, but they could also put
persistent upward pressure on unemployment,
as aected workers may need to seek new jobs
and perhaps new occupations. The pandemic
has also disrupted schooling at all levels,
which could have persistent negative eects
on educational attainment and economic
outcomes for aected students.
Financial Developments
The expected level of the federal funds
rate over the next few years has remained
near zero
Economic forecasters and nancial market
participants expect the federal funds rate over
the next several years to remain at the eective
lower bound. Market-based measures of
federal funds rate expectations over the next
few years have increased moderately since June
and remain below 0.25percent until the second
quarter of 2023 (gure29).
13
According to
the results of the Survey of Primary Dealers
and the Survey of Market Participants, both
conducted by the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York in January, the median respondent
views the most likely path of the federal funds
rate as remaining in its current range of 0 to
¼percent until the rst half of 2024.
14
13. These measures are based on a straight read of
market quotes and are not adjusted for term premiums.
14. The results of the Survey of Primary Dealers
and the Survey of Market Participants are available
on the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s website at
https://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/primarydealer_
survey_questions.html and https://www.newyorkfed.org/
markets/survey_market_participants, respectively.
February 16, 2021
.25
+
_
0
.25
.50
.75
1.00
1.25
Percent
202520242023202220212020
29. Market-implied federal funds rate path
Quarterly
June 11, 2020
N
OTE
: The federal funds rate path is implied by quotes on overnight
index swaps—a derivative contract tied to the eective federal funds rate.
The implied path as of June 11, 2020, is compared with that as o
f
February 16, 2021. The path is estimated with a spline approach,
assuming a term premium of 0 basis points. The June 11, 2020, path
extends through June 2024 and the February 16, 2021, path through
January 2025.
S
OURCE
:Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 27
Yields on longer-term U.S. nominal
Treasury securities increased markedly . . .
Yields on nominal Treasury securities at longer
maturities increased markedly since mid-2020
after falling sharply in late February and early
March as investors’ concerns regarding the
implications of the COVID-19 outbreak for
the economic outlook led to both falling policy
rate expectations and ight-to-safety ows
(gure30). The increase in yields on longer-
term Treasury securities followed news of the
imminent arrival of multiple highly eective
COVID-19 vaccines in the fall of 2020 and
expectations of further scal support, as well
as an increase in the issuance of longer-term
Treasury securities. Near-term uncertainty
about longer-dated nominal Treasury
yields—as measured by volatility of near-
term swaptions of 10-year interest rates—has
remained low.
. . . while spreads of other long-term debt
to Treasury securities narrowed . . .
Despite the rise in Treasury yields, yields on
30-year agency mortgage-backed securities
(MBS)—an important determinant of
mortgage interest rates—decreased somewhat,
on balance, amid the Federal Reserve’s
ongoing purchases of MBS and have remained
near their historical lows (gure31). Thus, the
spread between yields on 30-year agency MBS
and comparable-maturity Treasury yields has
narrowed.
Approval of the eective vaccines late last
year, optimism about further scal support,
and notable improvement in the outlook
for corporate earnings boosted investors’
optimism, and improvement in the credit
quality of rms drove declines in yields on
investment- and speculative-grade corporate
bonds (gure32). As with mortgage securities,
spreads on corporate bond yields over
comparable-maturity nominal Treasury
yields have narrowed considerably since
the end of June—as corporate bond yields
declined and yields on nominal Treasury
5-year
2-year
0
1
2
3
4
Percent
202120192017201520132011
30. Yields on nominal Treasury securities
Daily
10-year
S
OURCE
: Department of the Treasury via Haver Analytics.
Yield
0
50
100
150
200
250
Basis points
1
2
3
4
5
202120192017201520132011
31. Yield and spread on agency mortgage-backed
securities
Percent
Spread
N
OTE
: The yield is on mortgage-backed securities from Fannie Mae
through May 31, 2019, and from uniform mortgage-backed securities
thereafter. Data are daily.
S
OURCE
: Department of the Treasury; J.P. Morgan. Courtesy of J.P
.
Morgan Chase & Co., Copyright 2021.
28 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
securities increased—and have returned to
levels observed before the pandemic. Yields
on municipal debt continued to decline in the
second half of 2020, and spreads on municipal
bonds over comparable-maturity nominal
Treasury yields have narrowed substantially
since the end of June, as nominal Treasury
yields increased and investors grew more
optimistic about further scal stimulus and
aid to state and local governments. The year-
end expiration of lending facilities that were
authorized under section 13(3) of the Federal
Reserve Act and that use CARES Act funding
did not lead to upward pressure on corporate
or municipal bond spreads.
. . . and market functioning for Treasury
securities, corporate bonds, mortgage-
backed securities, and municipal bonds
continued to improve . . .
After having improved substantially in the
spring of last year, measures of market
liquidity for Treasury securities—such as
measures of market depth and trade sizes—
continued to improve somewhat in the second
half of 2020 and moved closer to pre-
pandemic levels, especially for shorter-dated
Treasury securities. However, measures of
liquidity for longer-dated Treasury securities
and in some portions of the MBS market—
notably for those securities excluded from
Federal Reserve open market purchases—
remained somewhat below pre-pandemic
levels. Measures of market functioning of the
corporate bond market continued to improve
as bid-ask spreads narrowed considerably
and returned to their pre-pandemic levels
and issuance of corporate bonds in primary
markets was robust. Measures of market
functioning of the municipal bond market—
such as robust issuance of municipal bonds in
primary markets and round-trip transaction
costs—indicate that market conditions
remained stable in the second half of 2020.
Municipal
High-yield corporate
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Percent
202120192017201520132011
32. Corporate bond yields, by securities rating, and
municipal bond yield
Daily
Investment-grade corporate
N
OTE
: Investment-grade corporate is the 10-year triple-B, which
reects the eective yield of the ICE BofAML 7-to-10-year triple-B U.S.
Corporate Index (C4A4). High-yield corporate is the 10-year high yiel
d
and reects the eective yield of the ICE BofAML 7-to-10-year U.S.
Cash Pay High Yield Index (J4A0). Municipal is the Municipal Market
Advisors 20-year yield.
S
OURCE
:ICE Data Indices, LLC, used with permission; Municipal
Market Advisors.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 29
. . . while conditions in short-term
funding markets remained stable
The eective federal funds rate and other
secured and unsecured short-term rates
continued to trade within the target range
of the federal funds rate, as ample liquidity,
primarily due to substantial increases in
reserves, has kept markets functioning
smoothly. Since June, measures of stress
in short-term funding markets—including
trading volumes, issuance, and spreads to
overnight index swaps—have remained stable
at or near pre-pandemic levels, and year-end
funding pressures were minimal.
Broad stock prices have risen notably
After starting to rebound last spring from
their COVID-related declines, broad stock
prices have risen notably further since
mid-2020, as the arrival of eective vaccines,
optimism about further scal support, and
notable improvement in the outlook for
corporate earnings outweighed investor
concerns regarding the rise in COVID-19
cases (gure33). The prospect of an economic
recovery aided by eective vaccines and
scal support led to outsized price gains in
some cyclical sectors, such as the consumer
discretionary, materials, and information
technology sectors. Similarly, stock prices
of smaller corporations considerably
outperformed large-cap stock price indexes.
After experiencing depressed levels through
early fall, bank stock price indexes increased
considerably in late 2020, boosted by positive
vaccine news, a generally improved investor
outlook for loan losses and bank protability,
and the release of favorable stress-test results
in late 2020. Measures of realized and
implied stock price volatility for the S&P 500
index—the 20-day realized volatility and the
VIX—decreased sharply from their very high
levels at the end of the second quarter but
remained moderately above their historical
medians, respectively (gure34). (For a
discussion of nancial stability issues, see
the box “Developments Related to Financial
Stability.”)
S&P 500 index
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
December 31, 2009 = 100
202120192017201520132011
33. Equity prices
Daily
Dow Jones bank index
S
OURCE: S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC via Bloomberg. (For Dow
Jones Indices licensing information, see the note on the Contents page.)
VIX
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Percent
202120192017201520132011
34. S&P 500 volatility
Daily
Realized volatility
N
OTE
: The VIX is a measure of implied volatility that represents the
expected annualized change in the S&P 500 index over the following 30
days. For realized volatility, 5-minute S&P 500 returns are used in an
exponentially weighted moving average with 75 percent of weight
distributed over the past 20 days.
S
OURCE
: Cboe Volatility Index® (VIX®) via Bloomberg; Federal
Reserve Board sta estimates.
30 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
elevated before the outbreak of the pandemic. Business
leverage now stands near historical highs. While near-
term risks associated with debt service may be limited
by large cash balances at large  rms, low interest rates,
and recently improved earnings prospects, insolvency
risks at small and medium-sized  rms, as well as at
some large  rms, remain considerable. The household
sector entered the downturn with relatively low debt
but experienced signi cant  nancial strains because
of the unprecedented spike in unemployment and
business closures. Government programs—including
expanded unemployment insurance and direct stimulus
payments in the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic
Security Act, or CARES Act—and a rebound in
economic activity in the second half of 2020 reduced
economic hardship for households and mitigated the
deterioration in household credit quality.
In the  nancial sector, bank pro tability and capital
positions, which were strained by the outbreak of
the pandemic, improved in the second half of 2020
because of a combination of lower-than-expected
losses, a better economic outlook, and restrictions
imposed by the Federal Reserve on capital distributions
by the largest banks. In particular, the capitalization of
U.S. global systemically important banks, or G-SIBs,
exceeds pre-pandemic levels. In addition, the results
of stress tests released in June and December2020
indicated that banks would generally remain well
capitalized under extremely severe recession scenarios.
Leverage at broker-dealers changed little over 2020 and
remains at historically low levels. While the liquidity
deterioration across dealer-intermediated markets in
March2020 demonstrated potential fragility despite
dealers’ low leverage, this fragility has been likely
mitigated by emergency lending facilities and the
supervisory action of the Federal Reserve. By contrast,
leverage at life insurance companies has risen to post-
2008 highs. Vulnerabilities from leverage at hedge
funds remain elevated. Finally, securitization volumes
increased after coming to a halt in March2020 but
remain signi cantly below pre-pandemic levels.
Over the course of 2020, banks relied only modestly
on short-term wholesale funding and maintained
signi cant levels of high-quality liquid assets. By
contrast, developments at the onset of the pandemic
demonstrated signi cant structural vulnerabilities at
money market mutual funds and open-end investment
funds, particularly those that invest substantially in
This discussion reviews vulnerabilities in the
U.S.  nancial system since the COVID-19 outbreak
and summarizes recent actions and developments
at facilities established by the Federal Reserve to
support the  ow of credit throughout the economy.
1
The framework used by the Federal Reserve Board for
assessing the resilience of the U.S.  nancial system
focuses on  nancial vulnerabilities in four broad areas:
asset valuations, business and household debt, leverage
in the  nancial sector, and funding risks.
Overall, asset valuation pressures, which were
elevated before the COVID-19 outbreak in the United
States, brie y subsided at the onset of the outbreak as
asset prices plummeted but have since retraced in most
markets. In particular, prices in equity, corporate bond,
and residential real estate (RRE) markets have returned
to or exceeded pre-pandemic levels, buoyed in part by
recent developments related to vaccines. Equity prices
have more than recovered from the steep declines
at the onset of the pandemic, with investor appetite
broadly rebounding across most sectors. Equity market
volatility remains high, indicating persistent uncertainty
regarding the pandemic and the related course of
economic activity. Yields on corporate bonds over
comparable-maturity Treasury securities have narrowed
considerably. Treasury yields across the maturity
spectrum declined at the onset of the pandemic and
remain near historical lows. The credit quality of
outstanding leveraged loans deteriorated early this year,
but investor appetite remains strong and new issuance
has increased in the second half of 2020. RRE prices
also rose rapidly in the second half of 2020, outpacing
rent increases. Commercial real estate prices remain
at historically high levels despite high vacancy rates
and appear susceptible to sharp declines, particularly
if the pace of distressed transactions picks up or, in the
longer term, the pandemic leads to permanent changes
in demand.
Vulnerabilities associated with business and
household debt increased over the course of 2020.
Business debt has risen from levels that were already
1. The Financial Stability Report published in November
2020 presents the most recent, detailed assessment of U.S.
nancial system vulnerabilities and a summary of Federal
Reserve actions and developments at facilities during the
COVID-19 crisis. See Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System (2020), Financial Stability Report (Washington:
Board of Governors, November), https://www.federalreserve.
gov/publications/files/financial-stability-report-20201109.pdf.
Developments Related to Financial Stability
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 31
The Paycheck Protection Program Liquidity Facility
(PPPLF) was established to extend credit to lenders
that participate in the Paycheck Protection Program of
the Small Business Administration (SBA), which has
provided payroll support for small businesses. Through
mid-January2021, the Federal Reserve has made nearly
15,000 PPPLF advances to more than 850 banking
institutions, totaling more than $110billion in liquidity.
The Federal Reserve has taken actions that reduce
spillovers to the U.S. economy from foreign  nancial
stresses. Temporary U.S. dollar liquidity swap lines
were established in March2020, in addition to the
preexisting standing lines, and have improved liquidity
conditions in dollar funding markets in the United
States and abroad by providing foreign central banks
with the capacity to deliver U.S. dollar funding to
institutions in their jurisdictions during times of market
stress. The FIMA (Foreign and International Monetary
Authorities) Repo Facility has helped support the
smooth functioning of the U.S. Treasury market by
providing a temporary source of U.S. dollars to a
broad range of countries, many of which do not have
swap line arrangements with the Federal Reserve. The
temporary swap lines and the FIMA Repo Facility will
continue to serve as liquidity backstops until their
scheduled expiration at the end of September2021.
Other facilities established at the onset of the
pandemic expired either at the end of December2020
or at the beginning of January2021. The Primary
Market Corporate Credit Facility, the Secondary
Market Corporate Credit Facility, and the Municipal
Liquidity Facility were established to improve the  ow
of credit through bond markets, where large  rms and
municipalities obtain most of their long-term funding.
The Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility was
also set up to support the issuance of securities backed
by student loans, auto loans, credit card loans, loans
backed by the SBA, and certain other assets. Altogether,
before expiring at the end of 2020, these facilities
brought rapid improvements to credit markets, with
only modest direct interventions. The Main Street
Lending Program (Main Street) expired at the beginning
of January2021. In its period of operation, Main Street
purchased about 1,800 loan participations, totaling
more than $16billion, which helped small and
medium-sized businesses from some of the hardest-
hit areas of the country and covered a wide range of
industries.
corporate and municipal debt. These funds experienced
large, sudden redemptions in March2020, which
contributed to strains in broader short-term funding
markets and  xed-income debt markets. Federal
Reserve actions, including emergency lending
facilities, have mitigated these vulnerabilities for now,
but without structural reforms, the vulnerabilities
demonstrated in March2020 will persist and could
signi cantly amplify future shocks.
The outlook for the pandemic and economic
activity remains uncertain globally. In response to
the economic disruptions caused by the pandemic,
many foreign governments have ramped up spending
to support households and businesses. Nevertheless,
nancial systems in some foreign economies are
more vulnerable than before the pandemic, and these
vulnerabilities may grow in the near term. Risks from
widespread and persistent stresses in emerging markets
and dollar funding markets could interact with risks
associated with the course of COVID-19 for the U.S.
nancial system. In turn, these risks could be ampli ed
by the vulnerabilities identi ed in this discussion and
produce additional strains for the U.S.  nancial system
and economic activity.
Developments Associated with Facilities
to Support the Economy during the
COVID-19 Crisis
In the immediate wake of the pandemic, the
Federal Reserve took forceful actions and established
emergency lending facilities, with the approval of the
Secretary of the Treasury as needed. These actions
and facilities have supported the  ow of credit to
households and businesses and have served as
backstop measures that have given investors con dence
that support will be available should conditions
deteriorate substantially.
Some of the facilities established at the onset of the
pandemic are still operational. The Commercial Paper
Funding Facility (CPFF), the Money Market Mutual
Fund Liquidity Facility (MMLF), and the Primary Dealer
Credit Facility (PDCF) stabilized short-term funding
markets and improved the  ow of credit to households
and businesses. Although balances in the PDCF,
CPFF, and MMLF have fallen from their initial highs
to low levels, the facilities will continue to serve as
important backstops against further market stress until
their scheduled expiration at the end of March2021.
32 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Bank credit contracted, while bank
protability improved
In contrast with strong debt issuance through
securities markets, outstanding bank loan
balances across most major loan categories
have contracted since mid-June amid generally
weak borrower demand and tight lending
standards. Commercial and industrial (C&I)
loans at banks declined sharply in the second
half of 2020, reecting the repayment of
large credit-line draws made earlier in the
year and the forgiveness of some loans under
the Paycheck Protection Program, as well as
generally weak borrower demand for such
loans and tighter bank lending standards.
However, overall C&I loan balances at banks
remained higher compared with a year earlier
(gure35). Measures of bank protability,
such as return on assets and return on
equity, rebounded in the second half of 2020
following very low readings in the second
quarter, when banks signicantly increased
their loan loss provisions, but have remained
below pre-pandemic levels (gure36).
Delinquency rates on bank loans remained
low, as banks’ loss-mitigation and forbearance
programs allowed many borrowers to stay
current on their loans. Large banks posted
higher-than-expected earnings in the fourth
quarter, bolstered by capital market activity
and loan loss reserve releases, while low rates
continued to weigh on prot margins.
International Developments
Economic activity abroad snapped back
in the third quarter . . .
As in the United States, foreign GDP partially
rebounded in the third quarter of 2020
(gure37). Nonetheless, foreign economic
90
100
110
120
130
140
150
160
2005 average = 100
20202018201620142012201020082006
37. Foreign real gross domestic product
Quarterly
NOTE: The data extend through 2020:Q3. Foreign GDP computed on
a representative sample of 40 countries and aggregated using U.S. trade
weights.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Database of Global
Economic Indicators, https://www.dallasfed.org/institute/dgei/gdp.aspx.
Return on assets
30
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
30
Percent, annual rate
2.0
1.5
1.0
.5
+
_
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
202020182016201420122010200820062004
36. Protability of bank holding companies
Percent, annual rate
Return on equity
N
OTE:The data are quarterly, extend through 2020:Q3, and are
seasonally adjusted.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Form FR Y-9C,
Consolidated
Financial Statements for Bank Holding Companies.
30
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
30
40
Percent
20212019201720152013201120092007
35. Commercial and industrial loan growth
Monthly
NOTE:Data are calculated as monthly year-over-year growth rates.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.8, “Assets a
nd
Liabilities of Commercial Banks in the United States.”
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 33
activity remains well below its pre-pandemic
level, as a resurgence of infections in many
economies has recently led to renewed social-
distancing restrictions. The accompanying
slowdown in economic activity appears to
have been less dramatic than that in the
spring, as economies have adjusted to function
better under social-distancing restrictions. In
addition, many current containment measures
have been less stringent relative to those in
the spring, and scal and monetary policies
continue to support the path to recovery.
Since last spring, manufacturing has generally
recovered more than services, which remain
depressed because consumers have avoided
socially intensive activities, especially in the
hospitality and leisure sectors (gure38).
Some higher-income Asian economies, where
infections are more under control, experienced
relatively better GDP growth than many
advanced economies and beneted from
increased export demand in the second half
of 2020. Most notably, China’s GDP was
6.5percent higher in the fourth quarter of2020
compared with a year ago. In many Latin
American countries and advanced foreign
economies (AFEs), fourth-quarter GDP
contracted relative to a year earlier (gure39).
Although the ongoing spread of the virus—
including new variants—is concerning,
many AFEs have already started immunizing
their populations and have commitments
to purchase substantial stocks of vaccines.
Controlling the virus globally, however, will be
challenging, in part because many emerging
market economies (EMEs) have more limited
access to vaccines and face greater distribution
challenges.
Euro area
Japan
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
65
Index
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
38. Services purchasing managers index in
selected foreign economies
Monthly
China
N
OTE: For the foreign services output purchasing managers index
(PMI), values greater than (less than) 50 indicate better (worse) business
conditions, on average, for the participants surveyed relative to
conditions at the time of the previous survey.
S
OURCE
: IHS Markit, Global Sector PMI.
8
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
Percent change from year earlier
Euro area Canada China Mexico South Korea
39. Real gross domestic product in selected
foreign economies
NOTE: The data are for 2020:Q4. For Canada, the euro area, and
Mexico, the values correspond to ash estimates of GDP. For South
Korea, the value is the advance GDP estimate. For China, the value
corresponds to preliminary GDP.
S
OURCE: For the euro area, Eurostat; for Canada, Statistics Canada;
for China, National Bureau of Statistics of China; for Mexico, Instituto
Nacional de Estadística y Geografía; for South Korea, Bank of Korea;
all via Haver Analytics.
34 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
. . . with considerable policy support and
subdued ination
Eorts to contain the virus’s resurgence in
the fourth quarter prompted some foreign
central banks and scal authorities to
provide additional support to households
and businesses, particularly in the AFEs.
High debt levels limited the scal space in
some EMEs, and emergency aid to sustain
employment and household spending
expired in some EMEs with elevated scal
concerns. Monetary policy across foreign
economies was highly accommodative, and
nancing conditions remained supportive of
growth, with a few major AFE central banks
introducing new stimulus measures late last
year. Indeed, market-implied policy paths
for the Japanese, U.K., and European central
banks signal a prolonged period of monetary
accommodation (gure40).
Even with substantial policy support, AFE
unemployment rates at the end of 2020 are
higher than they were before the pandemic.
Unemployment rates in Europe and Japan
rose moderately during the spring and have
remained relatively unchanged (gure41).
Canada, however, endured a large and rapid
increase in unemployment during the spring
and a commensurate decline by year-end,
similar to the U.S. experience. The country-
specic dynamics of unemployment partly
reect dierences in labor market structures,
employment protection regulations, and the
expansion of wage subsidy programs. In
general, unemployment rates in the EMEs
increased since the start of the pandemic, and
some Asian economies adopted direct wage
subsidies to avert large dislocations in their
labor markets.
United States
Euro area
Canada
Japan 2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
Percent
202120192017201520132011200920072005
41. Unemployment rate in selected advanced economies
Monthly
United Kingdom
N
OTE: The data for the United Kingdom extend through October
2020 and are centered 3-month averages of monthly data. The data for
the euro area and Japan extend through December 2020.
S
OURCE: For the United Kingdom, Oce for National Statistics; for
Japan, Ministry of Health, Labour, and Welfare; for the euro area,
Statistical Oce of the European Communities; for Canada, Statistics
Canada; for the United States, Bureau of Labor Statistics; all via Haver
Analytics.
Euro area
Japan
100
50
+
_
0
50
100
150
Basis points
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
40. 24-month policy expectations for selected advanced
foreign economies
Weekly
United Kingdom
N
OTE
: The data are weekly averages of daily 24-month market-implied
central bank policy rates. The 24-month policy rates are implied by
quotes on overnight index swaps tied to the policy rates. The data begin
on Thursdays and extend through February 10, 2021.
S
OURCE
: Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Board sta estimations.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 35
Despite the recovery in activity and
employment in some sectors of the economy,
lower overall demand and continued
uncertainty about the path of the virus helped
keep ination subdued abroad. In many
foreign economies, ination remains below
central banks’ targets. In the euro area and
Japan, the consumer price index fell in 2020,
reecting subdued ination expectations and
persistent economic slack (gure42).
Longer-term sovereign yields remained
low, while risk sentiment improved . . .
Longer-term sovereign yields in major
AFEs have moved up, on net, but remained
near historically low levels amid continued
monetary policy accommodation (gure43).
Foreign equity markets rebounded in the
second half of2020, reecting not only
supportive monetary and scal policies, but
also the development of eective vaccines.
Although AFE stock markets largely
recovered, they still underperformed U.S.
equities, with greater restrictions on activity
abroad and a lower share of companies that
beneted from the digital economy (gure44).
United States
Germany
Japan
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percent
2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021
43. Nominal 10-year government bond yields in
selected advanced economies
Weekly
United Kingdom
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily benchmark yields. The
data begin on Thursdays and extend through February 10, 2021.
S
OURCE
: Bloomberg.
Euro area
Canada
Japan
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
12-month percent change
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
42. Consumer price ination in selected advanced
foreign economies
Monthly
United Kingdom
N
OTE: The data extend through December 2020.
S
OURCE
: For the United Kingdom, Oce for National Statistics;
for
Japan,
Ministry of Internal Aairs and Communications; for the eur
o
area,
Statistical Oce of the European Communities; for C
anada,
Statistics Canada; all via Haver Analytics.
United States
Euro area
Japan
80
100
120
140
160
180
200
Week ending January 6, 2016 = 100
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
44. Equity indexes for selected advanced economies
Weekly
United
Kingdom
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily data. The data begin on
Thursdays and extend through February 10, 2021.
S
OURCE: For euro area, DJ Euro Stoxx Index; for Japan, TOPI
X
Stock Index; for United Kingdom, FTSE 100 Stock Index; for United
States, S&P 500 Index; all via Bloomberg. (For Dow Jones Indices
licensing information, see the note on the Contents page.)
36 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
EME equity markets have recovered since
the spring, with recent strong capital inows
(gure45). Asian equity indexes rose well
above pre-pandemic levels, while those in Latin
America posted modest gains relative to a year
ago, largely reecting Asian economies’ lower
infection rates, better fundamentals, and larger
scal space to provide additional stimulus
(gure46). Along with the improvement in
equity markets, sovereign borrowing spreads
generally narrowed, although they are still
above pre-pandemic levels.
. . . and the broad dollar depreciated
The broad dollar index—a measure of the
trade-weighted value of the dollar against
Taiwan
South Korea
Brazil
Mexico
50
100
150
200
250
300
Week ending January 6, 2016 = 100
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
46. Equity indexes for selected emerging market
economies
Weekly
China
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily data. The data begin on
Thursdays and extend through February 10, 2021.
S
OURCE: For China, Shanghai Composite Index; for Brazil, Bovespa
Index; for South Korea, Korean Composite Index; for Mexico, IPC
Index; for Taiwan, TAIEX; all via Bloomberg.
EMBI+ (left scale)
100
75
50
25
+
_
0
25
50
75
100
Billions of dollars
900
600
300
+
_
0
300
600
900
20212019201720152013201120092007
45. Emerging market mutual fund ows and spreads
Basis points
Jan.
N
OTE
: The bond and equity fund ows data are semiannual sums of
weekly data from December 28, 2006, to December 30, 2020, and a monthly
sum of weekly data from December 31, 2020, to January 26, 2021. Weekly
data span Thursday through Wednesday, and the semiannual and monthly
values are sums over weekly data for weeks ending in that half year or
month. The fund ows data exclude funds located in China. The J.P.
Morgan Emerging Markets Bond Index Plus (EMBI+) data are weekly
averages of daily data. The weekly data begin on Thursdays and extend
through February 10, 2021. The EMBI+ data exclude Venezuela.
S
OURCE
: For bond and equity fund ows, EPFR Global; for EMBI+, J.P.
Morgan Emerging Markets Bond Index Plus via Bloomberg.
Equity fund ows (right scale)
Bond fund ows (right scale)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 37
foreign currencies—fell in the second half of
last year. Both the continued improvement
in market conditions following the stresses
of last March and highly accommodative
U.S. monetary policy contributed to dollar
depreciation. On balance, the dollar has
depreciated about 3.5 percent relative to a year
ago (gure 47). The dollar broadly weakened
against AFE currencies, notably the euro. The
dollar also fell against some Asian emerging
market currencies, particularly the Chinese
renminbi and Korean won (gure 48).
AFE dollar index
EME dollar index
90
95
100
105
110
115
120
Week ending January 6, 2016 = 100
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
47. U.S. dollar exchange rate indexes
Weekly
Broad dollar index
Dollar appreciation
N
OTE: The data, which are in foreign currency units per dollar, are
weekly averages of daily values of the broad dollar index, advanced
foreign economies (AFE) dollar index, and emerging market economies
(EME) dollar index. The weekly data begin on Thursdays and extend
through February 10, 2021. As indicated by the leftmost arrow, increases
in the data reflect U.S. dollar appreciation and decreases reflect U.S.
dollar depreciation.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.10, “Foreign
Exchange Rates.”
Korean won
Brazilian real
Mexican peso
70
80
90
100
110
120
130
140
150
Week ending January 6, 2016 = 100
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
48. Exchange rate indexes for selected emerging market
economies
Weekly
Chinese renminbi
Dollar appreciation
N
OTE: The data, which are in foreign currency units per dollar, are
weekly averages of daily data. The weekly data begin on Thursdays and
extend through February 10, 2021. As indicated by the leftmost arrow,
increases in the data reflect U.S. dollar appreciation and decreases reflect
U.S. dollar depreciation.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.10,Foreign
Exchange Rates.”
39
The Federal Open Market Committee
maintained the federal funds rate near
zero as it seeks to achieve maximum
employment and ination at the rate of
2percent over the longer run . . .
In light of the eects of the continuing
public health crisis on the economy and the
associated risks to the outlook, the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC) has
maintained the target range for the federal
funds rate at 0 to ¼percent since March2020,
when the global pandemic led the Committee
to quickly lower the target range to the
eective lower bound (gure49).
15
In its
revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals and
Monetary Policy Strategy, issued in August,
the Committee rearmed its commitment to
achieving maximum employment and ination
at the rate of 2 percent over the longer run and
noted that “following periods when ination
has been running persistently below 2percent,
15. See the FOMC statements issued since the
March meetings, which are available (along with other
postmeeting statements) on the Monetary Policy portion
of the Board’s website at https://www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy.htm.
appropriate monetary policy will likely
aim to achieve ination moderately above
2percent for some time” so that ination
averages 2percent over time and longer-term
ination expectations remain well anchored
at 2percent. (See the box “The FOMC’s
Revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals and
Monetary Policy Strategy.”) The Committee
expects to maintain an accommodative stance
of monetary policy until these outcomes are
achieved and has indicated that it expects
it will be appropriate to maintain the target
range for the federal funds rate at 0 to
¼percent until labor market conditions have
reached levels consistent with the Committee’s
assessments of maximum employment and
ination has risen to 2percent and is on track
to moderately exceed 2percent for some time.
. . . and the Committee increased the
holdings of Treasury securities and agency
mortgage-backed securities in the System
Open Market Account
In addition, the Federal Reserve has continued
to expand its holdings of Treasury securities
by $80billion per month and its holdings of
Part 2
monetary PoLiCy
2-year Treasury rate
Target federal funds rate
0
1
2
3
4
5
Percent
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
49.
Selected interest rates
Daily
10-year Treasury rate
N
OTE
: The 2-year and 10-year Treasury rates are the constant-maturity yields based on the most actively traded securities.
S
OURCE
: Department of the Treasury; Federal Reserve Board.
40 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
the Congress to promote maximum employment, price
stability, and moderate long-term interest rates. It also
describes the bene ts of explaining policy actions to
the public as clearly as possible. The statement then
outlines important changes to the characterization of
the Committee’s policy framework for achieving its
dual-mandate goals of maximum employment and
price stability. After stating that economic variables
uctuate in response to disturbances and that monetary
policy plays an important role in stabilizing the
economy, the statement notes that the Committee’s
primary means of adjusting policy is through changes in
the policy interest rate (the target range for the federal
funds rate). Furthermore, because the neutral level of
the policy rate is now lower than its historical average,
“the federal funds rate is likely to be constrained by
its effective lower bound more frequently than in the
past.Therefore, “the Committee judges that downward
risks to employment and in ation have increased.The
statement then notes that the “Committee is prepared
to use its full range of tools to achieve its maximum
employment and price stability goals,” indicating that
it could deploy other policy tools, such as forward
guidance and asset purchases, when the policy rate is
at its ELB.
In its revised statement, the Committee characterizes
maximum employment as a “broad-based and inclusive
goal” in addition to saying—as it did in the 2012
statement—that maximum employment is not directly
measurable and that it changes over time and depends
largely on nonmonetary factors. During the Fed Listens
events that were a pillar of the review of monetary
policy strategy, tools, and communication practices,
policymakers heard from a broad range of stakeholders
in the U.S. economy about how monetary policy affects
peoples’ daily lives and livelihoods.
2
2. Between February2019 and May2020, the Federal
Reserve System hosted 15 Fed Listens events with
representatives of the public. See Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System (2020), Fed Listens: Perspectives
On August27, 2020, the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) issued a revised Statement on
Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy.
1
This
document,  rst released in January2012, lays out
the Committee’s goals, articulates its framework for
monetary policy, and serves as the foundation for its
policy actions. The revised statement encapsulates the
key conclusions from the Federal Reserve’s review of
the monetary policy strategy, tools, and communication
practices it uses to pursue its statutory dual-mandate
goals of maximum employment and price stability.
The review, which commenced in early 2019, was
undertaken because the U.S. economy has changed
in ways that matter for monetary policy. In particular,
the neutral level of the policy interest rate—the policy
rate consistent with the economy operating at full
strength and with stable in ation—has fallen over
recent decades in the United States and abroad. This
decline in the neutral policy rate increases the risk
that the effective lower bound (ELB) on interest rates
will constrain central banks from reducing their policy
interest rates enough to effectively support economic
activity during downturns. In addition, during the
economic expansion that followed the Global Financial
Crisis—the longest U.S. expansion on record—the
unemployment rate hovered near 50-year lows for
roughly 2 years, resulting in new jobs and opportunities
for many who have typically been left behind. At the
same time, with brief exceptions, in ation ran below
the Committee’s 2percent objective.
The revised statement begins by reaf rming the
Committee’s commitment to its statutory mandate from
1. The FOMC’s revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals
and Monetary Policy Strategy, which was unanimously
reaf rmed at the FOMC’s January2021 meeting, appears in
the front matter of this report. Additional information about
the Federal Reserve’s review of monetary policy strategy, tools,
and communication practices and the revised statement is
available on the Board’s website at https://www.federalreserve.
gov/monetarypolicy/review-of-monetary-policy-strategy-tools-
and-communications.htm.
The FOMC’s Revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals and
Monetary Policy Strategy
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 41
the FOMC’s policy actions to achieve maximum
employment and price stability will be most effective
if longer-term in ation expectations remain well
anchored at 2percent. However, if in ation runs
below 2percent following economic downturns but
never moves above 2percent even when the economy
is strong, then, over time, in ation will average less
than 2percent. Households and businesses will
come to expect this result, meaning that in ation
expectations would tend to move below the 2percent
in ation goal and pull down realized in ation. Lower
in ation expectations also pull down the level of
nominal interest rates, further diminishing the scope
for monetary policy to reduce the policy rate during a
downturn and further worsening economic outcomes.
To prevent in ation expectations from falling below
2percent and the adverse cycle that could ensue,
the statement indicates that “the Committee seeks to
achieve in ation that averages 2percent over time,
and therefore judges that, following periods when
in ation has been running persistently below 2percent,
appropriate monetary policy will likely aim to achieve
in ation moderately above 2percent for some time.
The revised statement acknowledges that
“sustainably achieving maximum employment and
price stability depends on a stable  nancial system.
Therefore, as with the 2012 statement, the Committee’s
policy decisions will take into account “its assessments
of the balance of risks, including risks to the  nancial
system that could impede the attainment” of the
statutory goals.
The Committee concludes its revised statement by
indicating its intention to undertake a review of the
Federal Reserve’s monetary policy strategy, tools, and
communication practices roughly every  ve years.
Conducting a review at regular intervals is a good
institutional practice, provides valuable feedback, and
enhances transparency and accountability.
expenditures, is most consistent over the longer run with the
Federal Reserve’s statutory mandate.
A key takeaway from these events was that a strong
labor market during the late stages of an economic
expansion—conditions that were in effect in 2019 and
early 2020—offers signi cant bene ts to residents of
low- and moderate-income communities, primarily by
providing employment opportunities for people who
have had dif culty  nding jobs in the past.
The revised statement says that “the Committee’s
policy decisions must be informed by assessments of
the shortfalls [emphasis added] of employment from
its maximum level” rather than by “deviations”—
the word used in the earlier statement.
3
In previous
decades, in ation tended to rise noticeably in response
to a strengthening labor market. It was sometimes
appropriate for the Fed to tighten monetary policy as
employment rose toward its estimated maximum level
in order to stave off an unwelcome rise in in ation.
The change to “shortfalls” clari es that, in the
future, the Committee will not have concerns when
employment runs at or above real-time estimates of
its maximum level unless accompanied by signs of
unwanted increases in in ation or the emergence of
other risks that could impede the attainment of the
dual-mandate goals.
The Committee’s longer-run goal for in ation
remains 2percent, unchanged from the 2012
statement.
4
The revised statement emphasizes that
from the Public (Washington: Board of Governors,
June), https://www.federalreserve.gov/publications/files/
fedlistens-report-20200612.pdf. In addition, see the box
“Federal Reserve Review of Monetary Policy Strategy, Tools,
and Communication Practices” in Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System (2020), Monetary Policy
Report (Washington: Board of Governors, February),
pp.40–41, https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/
files/20200207_mprfullreport.pdf.
3. The most recent version of the 2012 statement is
available on the Board’s website at https://www.federalreserve.
gov/monetarypolicy/files/FOMC_LongerRunGoals_201901.pdf.
4. The in ation goal is measured by the annual change
in the price index for personal consumption expenditures.
The statement says: “The Committee reaf rms its judgment
that in ation at the rate of 2percent, as measured by the
annual change in the price index for personal consumption
the Congress to promote maximum employment, price
stability, and moderate long-term interest rates. It also
describes the bene ts of explaining policy actions to
the public as clearly as possible. The statement then
outlines important changes to the characterization of
the Committee’s policy framework for achieving its
dual-mandate goals of maximum employment and
price stability. After stating that economic variables
uctuate in response to disturbances and that monetary
policy plays an important role in stabilizing the
economy, the statement notes that the Committee’s
primary means of adjusting policy is through changes in
the policy interest rate (the target range for the federal
funds rate). Furthermore, because the neutral level of
the policy rate is now lower than its historical average,
“the federal funds rate is likely to be constrained by
its effective lower bound more frequently than in the
past.Therefore, “the Committee judges that downward
risks to employment and in ation have increased.The
statement then notes that the “Committee is prepared
to use its full range of tools to achieve its maximum
employment and price stability goals,” indicating that
it could deploy other policy tools, such as forward
guidance and asset purchases, when the policy rate is
at its ELB.
In its revised statement, the Committee characterizes
maximum employment as a “broad-based and inclusive
goal” in addition to saying—as it did in the 2012
statement—that maximum employment is not directly
measurable and that it changes over time and depends
largely on nonmonetary factors. During the Fed Listens
events that were a pillar of the review of monetary
policy strategy, tools, and communication practices,
policymakers heard from a broad range of stakeholders
in the U.S. economy about how monetary policy affects
peoples’ daily lives and livelihoods.
2
2. Between February2019 and May2020, the Federal
Reserve System hosted 15 Fed Listens events with
representatives of the public. See Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System (2020), Fed Listens: Perspectives
On August27, 2020, the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) issued a revised Statement on
Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy.
1
This
document,  rst released in January2012, lays out
the Committee’s goals, articulates its framework for
monetary policy, and serves as the foundation for its
policy actions. The revised statement encapsulates the
key conclusions from the Federal Reserve’s review of
the monetary policy strategy, tools, and communication
practices it uses to pursue its statutory dual-mandate
goals of maximum employment and price stability.
The review, which commenced in early 2019, was
undertaken because the U.S. economy has changed
in ways that matter for monetary policy. In particular,
the neutral level of the policy interest rate—the policy
rate consistent with the economy operating at full
strength and with stable in ation—has fallen over
recent decades in the United States and abroad. This
decline in the neutral policy rate increases the risk
that the effective lower bound (ELB) on interest rates
will constrain central banks from reducing their policy
interest rates enough to effectively support economic
activity during downturns. In addition, during the
economic expansion that followed the Global Financial
Crisis—the longest U.S. expansion on record—the
unemployment rate hovered near 50-year lows for
roughly 2 years, resulting in new jobs and opportunities
for many who have typically been left behind. At the
same time, with brief exceptions, in ation ran below
the Committee’s 2percent objective.
The revised statement begins by reaf rming the
Committee’s commitment to its statutory mandate from
1. The FOMC’s revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals
and Monetary Policy Strategy, which was unanimously
reaf rmed at the FOMC’s January2021 meeting, appears in
the front matter of this report. Additional information about
the Federal Reserve’s review of monetary policy strategy, tools,
and communication practices and the revised statement is
available on the Board’s website at https://www.federalreserve.
gov/monetarypolicy/review-of-monetary-policy-strategy-tools-
and-communications.htm.
The FOMC’s Revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals and
Monetary Policy Strategy
(continued)
42 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS) by
$40billion per month. These asset purchases
help foster smooth market functioning and
accommodative nancial conditions, thereby
supporting the ow of credit to households
and businesses. The Committee’s current
guidance regarding asset purchases indicates
that increases in the holdings of Treasury
securities and agency MBS in the System Open
Market Account will continue at least at this
pace until substantial further progress has been
made toward its maximum-employment and
price-stability goals. In addition, the minutes
of the January2021 FOMC meeting noted the
importance attached to clear communications
about the Committee’s assessment of progress
toward its longer-run goals well in advance
of the time when progress could be judged
substantial enough to warrant a change in the
pace of purchases.
16
The FOMC is committed to using its full
range of tools to promote maximum
employment and price stability
The ongoing public health crisis continues to
weigh on economic activity, employment, and
ination, and it poses considerable risks to
the economic outlook. The Federal Reserve is
committed to using its full range of tools to
support the U.S. economy in this challenging
time, thereby promoting its maximum-
employment and price-stability goals. The
Committee will continue to monitor the
implications of incoming information for the
economic outlook and is prepared to adjust
the stance of monetary policy as appropriate if
risks emerge that could impede the attainment
of the Committee’s goals. The Committee’s
assessments will take into account a wide
range of information, including readings
on public health, labor market conditions,
ination pressures and ination expectations,
and nancial and international developments.
In addition to evaluating a wide range of
economic and nancial data and information
16. The minutes for the January 2021 FOMC meeting
are available on the Board’s website at https://www.
federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomccalendars.htm.
gathered from business contacts and other
informed parties around the country,
policymakers routinely consult prescriptions
for the policy interest rate provided by various
monetary policy rules. Such prescriptions can
provide useful benchmarks for the FOMC.
Although simple rules cannot capture the
complexities of monetary policy and many
practical considerations make it undesirable
for the FOMC to adhere strictly to the
prescriptions of any specic rule, some
principles of good monetary policy can be
illustrated by these policy rules (see the box
“Monetary Policy Rules and Shortfalls from
Maximum Employment”).
The size of the Federal Reserve’s balance
sheet has grown since the end of June,
reecting continued asset purchases
of U.S. Treasury securities and agency
mortgage-backed securities
The Federal Reserve’s balance sheet has grown
to $7.4 trillion from $7trillion at the end of
June, reecting continued asset purchases to
help foster accommodative nancial conditions
and smooth market functioning, thereby
supporting the ow of credit to households
and businesses (gure50). The Federal
Reserve has continued rolling over at auction
all principal payments from its holdings
of Treasury securities. Principal payments
received from agency MBS and agency
debt continue to be reinvested into agency
MBS. Agency commercial mortgage-backed
securities purchases have also continued, but in
very small amounts.
The increase in asset holdings on the Federal
Reserve’s balance sheet due to Treasury
securities and agency MBS purchases has been
partially oset by declines in several other
asset categories. Outstanding balances at many
of the Federal Reserve’s emergency liquidity
and credit facilities have declined since June.
17
17. A list of funding, credit, liquidity, and loan
facilities established by the Federal Reserve in response to
COVID-19 is available on the Board’s website at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/funding-credit-liquidity-
and-loan-facilities.htm.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 43
In particular, outstanding balances for the
Primary Dealer Credit Facility, Commercial
Paper Funding Facility, and Money Market
Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility have all fallen
to near zero. Draws on central bank liquidity
swap lines have decreased substantially, and,
despite continued large-scale oerings, usage
of repurchase operations has been essentially
zero since their minimum bid rate was
increased in mid-June (gure51).
The expansion in the balance sheet was
accompanied by a substantial increase in
Federal Reserve liabilities, including reserve
balances held by depository institutions as well
as nonreserve liabilities such as currency and
other deposits.
The Federal Reserve concluded the
review of its strategic framework for
monetary policy in the second half
of2020
Over 2019 and 2020, the Federal Reserve
conducted a broad review of the monetary
policy strategy, tools, and communication
practices it uses to pursue its statutory dual-
mandate goals of maximum employment and
price stability. In addition to the release of
500
1,000
1,500
2,000
2,500
3,000
3,500
4,000
4,500
Billions of dollars
Feb. May Aug. Nov. Feb.
2020 2021
51. Federal Reserve open market operations
Daily
NOTE: The data are at a business-day frequency, excluding
federal
holidays. The data begin January 1, 2020. Repo is repurchase agreement.
MBS is mortgage-backed security. Key identies bars in order from
top
to bottom.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve B
oard
sta calculations.
Overnight repos
Outstanding term repos
Cumulative MBS purchases
Cumulative coupon purchases
Cumulative bill purchases
Trillions of dollars
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
50.
Federal Reserve assets and liabilities
Weekly
8
6
4
2
+
0
-
2
4
6
8
Other assets
Credit and liquidity
Agency debt and mortgage-backed securities holdings
Treasury securities held outright
Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Deposits of depository institutions
Capital and other liabilities
N
OTE
: “Agency debt and mortgage-backed securities holdings” includes agency residential mortgage-backed securities and agency commercial
mortgage-backed
securities. “Credit and liquidity facilities” consists of primary, secondary, and seasonal credit; term auction credit; central bank liquidity swaps;
support
for Maiden Lane, Bear Stearns Companies, Inc., and AIG; and other credit and liquidity facilities, including the Primary Dealer Credit Facility, the
Asset-Backed
Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility, the Commercial Paper Funding Facility, the Term Asset-Backed Securities
Loan
Facility, the Primary and Secondary Market Corporate Credit Facilities, the Paycheck Protection Program Liquidity Facility, the Municipal Liquidity
Facility,
and the Main Street Lending Program. “Other assets” includes repurchase agreements, FIMA (Foreign and International Monetary Authorities)
repurchase
agreements, and unamortized premiums and discounts on securities held outright. “Capital and other liabilities” includes reverse repurchase
agreements,
the U.S. Treasury General Account, and the U.S. Treasury Supplementary Financing Account. The data extend through February 10, 2021. Key
identies shaded areas in order from top to bottom.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, “Factors Aecting Reserve Balances.”
44 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
the revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals
and Monetary Policy Strategy in August (see
the box “The FOMC’s Revised Statement
on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy
Strategy”), analytical work that was prepared
by Federal Reserve System sta and that
served as background to the review was
released to the public.
18
In December, two changes were made to the
Summary of Economic Projections (SEP)
18. A report on the Fed Listens initiative, a key
component of the review process, was released in
June2020 and is available on the Board’s website at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/publications/files/
fedlistens-report-20200612.pdf. The analytical materials
prepared by System sta are accessible from the Board’s
main webpage on the review (https://www.federalreserve.
gov/monetarypolicy/review-of-monetary-policy-strategy-
tools-and-communications.htm).
to enhance the information provided to the
public. First, the release of the full set of
SEP exhibits was accelerated by three weeks:
Starting with the December2020 meeting,
the FOMC began releasing all SEP exhibits
on the day of the policy decision (following
the conclusion of an FOMC meeting) rather
than with the release of the FOMC meeting
minutes. As such, the written summary of
the projections that had been included as an
addendum to the minutes of the corresponding
FOMC meeting was discontinued. Second, two
new exhibits were added that display a time
series of diusion indexes for participants’
judgments of uncertainty and risks. These
diusion indexes illustrate how FOMC
participants’ assessments of uncertainties and
risks have evolved over time.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 45
considerations, the Federal Open Market Committee’s
(FOMC) revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals
and Monetary Policy Strategy refers to “shortfalls
of employment” from the Committee’s assessment
of its maximum level rather than the “deviations of
employment” used in the previous statement.
2
This
change has important implications for the design of
simple interest rate rules.
This discussion examines the prescriptions from
a number of commonly studied monetary policy
rules, along with the prescriptions from a modi ed
simple rule that, all else being equal, would not call
for increasing the policy rate as employment moves
higher and unemployment drops below its estimated
longer-run level. This modi ed rule aims to illustrate,
in a simple way, the Committee’s focus on shortfalls
of employment from assessments of its maximum
level. Other key changes to the Committee’s monetary
policy strategy, including the aim of having in ation
average 2percent over time to ensure that longer-
term in ation expectations remain well anchored, are
not incorporated in the simple rules analyzed in this
discussion.
Policy Rules: Some Key Design Principles
and Limitations
In many stylized models of the economy, desirable
economic outcomes can be achieved by following a
monetary policy rule that incorporates key principles
of good monetary policy. One such principle is that
monetary policy should respond in a predictable way to
changes in economic conditions, thus fostering public
understanding of policymakers’ goals and strategy.
3
A second principle is that, to stabilize in ation, the
policy rate should be adjusted over time in response
to persistent increases or decreases in in ation to an
extent suf cient to ensure a return of in ation to the
longer-run objective.
2. See the box “The FOMC’s Revised Statement on Longer-
Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy” (earlier in Part 2)
for a discussion of this change and other changes made to the
statement.
3. The effectiveness of monetary policy is enhanced when
it is well understood by the public. For a discussion of how
the public’s understanding of monetary policy matters for the
effectiveness of monetary policy, see Janet L. Yellen (2012),
“Revolution and Evolution in Central Bank Communications,
speech delivered at the Haas School of Business, University
of California, Berkeley, November13, https://www.
federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20121113a.htm.
Simple interest rate rules relate a policy interest
rate, such as the federal funds rate, to a small number
of other economic variables—typically including
the deviation of in ation from its target value
and a measure of resource slack in the economy.
Policymakers consult policy rate prescriptions derived
from a variety of policy rules as part of their monetary
policy deliberations without mechanically following the
prescriptions of any particular rule. Most rules analyzed
in the research literature respond to deviations—both
positive and negative—of resource utilization from its
longer-run level because their design was informed
by historical periods and economic models in which
high resource utilization and a strong labor market
are accompanied by in ation pressure and in which
policy rates remain well above the effective lower
bound(ELB).
Economic performance in recent decades,
including during the previous economic expansion,
has demonstrated that a strong labor market can be
sustained without inducing an unwanted increase in
in ation. During that expansion, the unemployment
rate fell to low levels—it remained at or below
4percent from early 2018 until the start of the
pandemic—bringing many bene ts to families and
communities that, all too often, had been left behind,
with no sign of excessive pressures on prices. The
lack of undue in ation pressures during this period
illustrates that a strong labor market, by itself, need
not cause concern unless accompanied by signs of
unwanted increases in in ation or the emergence
of other risks that could impede the attainment of
the Committee’s goals. In addition, the expansion
reinforced the view that assessments of the maximum
level of employment are imprecise and may change
over time.
1
Tightening monetary policy in the absence
of evidence of excessive in ation pressures may
result in an unwarranted loss of opportunity for
many Americans, whereas if an undue increase in
in ation were to arise, policymakers would have the
tools to address such an increase. Re ecting these
1. In recent years, forecasters covered by the Blue Chip
Survey, as well as FOMC participants in the Summary of
Economic Projections, have substantially reduced their
implied estimates of the unemployment rate that is sustainable
in the longer run. For a discussion, see the box “Monetary
Policy Rules and Uncertainty in Monetary Policy Settings”
in Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2020),
Monetary Policy Report (Washington: Board of Governors,
February), pp. 33–37, https://www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy/files/20200207_mprfullreport.pdf.
Monetary Policy Rules and Shortfalls from Maximum Employment
(continued on next page)
46 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
Policy Rules: Historical Prescriptions
Economists have analyzed many monetary policy
rules, including the well-known Taylor(1993) rule, the
“balanced approach” rule, the “adjusted Taylor(1993)”
rule, and the “ rst difference” rule.
6
In addition to these
rules, gure A shows a “balanced approach (shortfalls)”
rule, which represents one simple way to illustrate
the Committee’s focus on shortfalls from maximum
employment. All of the policy rules analyzed in this
discussion embody the key principles of good monetary
policy previously noted. They are also subject to the
associated limitations. Thus, the balanced-approach
(shortfalls) rule, as is the case with all simple rules, does
not fully capture the monetary policy strategy that the
FOMC announced in August2020.
All  ve rules feature the unemployment rate gap,
measured as the difference between an estimate of the
rate of unemployment in the longer run (u
t
LR
) and the
current unemployment rate; the  rst-difference rule
includes the change in the unemployment rate gap
rather than its level.
7
All of the rules abstract from the
uncertainty affecting estimates of the unemployment
rate gap. In addition, all of the rules include the
6. The Taylor(1993) rule was suggested in John B. Taylor
(1993), “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,Carnegie-
Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39
(December), pp. 195–214. The balanced-approach rule was
analyzed in John B. Taylor (1999), “A Historical Analysis of
Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor, ed., Monetary Policy
Rules (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 319–41. The
adjusted Taylor(1993) rule was studied in David Reifschneider
and John C. Williams (2000), “Three Lessons for Monetary
Policy in a Low-In ation Era,Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, vol. 32 (November), pp. 936–66. The  rst-difference
rule is based on a rule suggested in Athanasios Orphanides
(2003), “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor
Rule,Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (July), pp. 983–
1022. A review of policy rules is in John B. Taylor and John
C. Williams (2011), “Simple and Robust Rules for Monetary
Policy,” in Benjamin M. Friedman and Michael Woodford,
eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol.3B (Amsterdam:
North-Holland), pp. 829–59. The same volume of the
Handbook of Monetary Economics also discusses approaches
other than policy rules for deriving policy rate prescriptions.
7. The original Taylor(1993) rule represented slack in
resource utilization using an output gap (the difference
between the current level of real gross domestic product
(GDP) and the level that GDP would be if the economy
were operating at maximum employment, measured in
percent of the latter). The rules in gure A represent slack in
resource utilization using the unemployment rate gap instead,
because that gap better captures the FOMC’s statutory goal
to promote maximum employment. However, movements in
these alternative measures of resource utilization are highly
correlated. For more information, see the note below gure A.
Simple monetary policy rules also have important
limitations. A  rst limitation is that many formulations
of simple rules do not recognize that the ELB limits the
extent that the policy rate can be lowered to support
the economy, which may impart a downward bias to
both in ation and in ation expectations. As part of
the FOMC’s revised strategy to mitigate the challenges
posed by the ELB and anchor longer-term in ation
expectations at 2percent, the Committee states that it
“seeks to achieve in ation that averages 2percent over
time, and therefore judges that, following periods when
in ation has been running persistently below 2percent,
appropriate monetary policy will likely aim to achieve
in ation moderately above 2percent for some time.
None of the simple rules analyzed in this discussion
take into account average in ation performance or
developments in measures of in ation expectations. As
such, they do not re ect this important aspect of the
FOMC’s monetary policy strategy.
4
A second limitation is that simple rules respond
to only a small set of economic variables and thus
necessarily abstract from many of the considerations
taken into account by the FOMC. For example,
a simple rule might respond to movements in a
speci c labor market indicator, such as the overall
unemployment rate. However, no single labor market
indicator can precisely capture the size of the shortfall
from maximum employment or identify when a strong
labor market can be sustained without putting undue
upward pressure on in ation.
5
A third limitation of
simple rules for the policy rate is that they generally
do not recognize the fact that the monetary policy
toolkit includes other tools—notably, large-scale asset
purchases and forward guidance, which are especially
relevant when the policy rate is near or at the ELB.
4. For a discussion of policy strategies that seek to make up
for past in ation shortfalls, see Jonas Arias, Martin Bodenstein,
Hess Chung, Thorsten Drautzburg, and Andrea Raffo (2020),
Alternative Strategies: How Do They Work? How Might They
Help?” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2020-068
(Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, August), https://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2020.068;
and James Hebden, Edward P. Herbst, Jenny Tang, Giorgio
Topa, and Fabian Winkler (2020), “How Robust Are Makeup
Strategies to Key Alternative Assumptions?” Finance and
Economics Discussion Series 2020-069 (Washington: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August),
https://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2020.069.
5. See Lael Brainard (2020), “Achieving a Broad-Based and
Inclusive Recovery,” speech delivered at “Post-COVID—Policy
Challenges for the Global Economy,” Society of Professional
Economists Annual Online Conference (via webcast),
October21, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/
speech/brainard20201021a.htm.
(continued)
Monetary Policy Rules (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 47
Contrary to the other simple rules featured here,
the adjusted Taylor(1993) rule recognizes that the
federal funds rate cannot be reduced materially below
the ELB. To make up for the cumulative shortfall in
accommodation following a recession during which
the federal funds rate has fallen to its ELB, the adjusted
Taylor(1993) rule prescribes only a gradual return of
the policy rate to the (positive) levels prescribed by the
standard Taylor(1993) rule after the economy begins
torecover.
Figure B shows historical prescriptions for the
federal funds rate from the  ve rules. For each period,
the  gure reports the policy rates prescribed by
the rules, taking as given the prevailing economic
conditions and estimates of u
t
LR
and r
t
LR
at the time.
The four rules whose formulas do not impose the ELB
imply prescriptions of strongly negative policy rates in
response to the pandemic-driven recession, well below
their respective troughs in the 2008–09 recession. These
deeply negative prescribed policy rates show the extent
to which policymakers’ ability to support the economy
through cuts in the policy rate was constrained by
difference between in ation and the FOMC’s longer-
run objective of 2percent. All but the  rst-difference
rule include an estimate of the neutral real interest rate
in the longer run (r
t
LR
).
8
By construction, the balanced-approach (shortfalls)
rule prescribes identical policy rates to those prescribed
by the balanced-approach rule at times when the
unemployment rate is above its estimated longer-run
level. However, when the unemployment rate is below
that level, the balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule is
more accommodative than the balanced-approach rule
because it does not call for the policy rate to rise as the
unemployment rate drops further.
8. The neutral real interest rate in the longer run (r
t
LR
) is
the level of the real federal funds rate that is expected to be
consistent, in the longer run, with maximum employment
and stable in ation. Like u
t
LR
, r
t
LR
is determined largely by
nonmonetary factors. The expression of the  rst-difference
rule shown in gure A does not involve an estimate of r
t
LR
.
However, this rule has its own shortcomings. For example,
research suggests that this sort of rule often results in greater
volatility in employment and in ation relative to what
would be obtained under the Taylor(1993) and balanced-
approachrules. (continued on next page)
Taylor (1993) rule
93
= + +0.5
(
)
+(
)
= + +0.5
(
)
+2(
)
=+
+0.5
(
)
+
(
{, 0}
)
Adjusted Taylor (1993) rule
93
= {
93
, ELB}
=
−1
+0.5
(
)
+
(
)
−(
−4
−4
)
A. Monetary policy rules
Balanced-approach rule
Balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule
First-dierence rule
n
2
N: R
t
T93
, R
t
BA
, R
t
BAS
, R
t
T93adj
, and R
t
FD
represent the values of the nominal federal funds rate prescribed by the Taylor
(1993), balanced-approach, balanced-approach (shortfalls), adjusted Taylor (1993), and rst-dierence rules, respectively.
R
t
denotes the realized nominal federal funds rate for quarter t, π
t
is the four-quarter price ination for quarter t, u
t
is the
unemployment rate in quarter
t, and r
t
LR
is the level of the neutral real federal funds rate in the longer run that is expected to be
consistent with sustaining maximum employment and ination at the FOMC’s 2percent longer-run objective, denoted
π
LR
. In
addition,
u
t
LR
is the rate of unemployment expected in the longer run. Z
t
is the cumulative sum of past deviations of the federal
funds rate from the prescriptions of the Taylor (1993) rule when that rule prescribes setting the federal funds rate below an
ELB of 12.5 basis points.
The Taylor (1993) rule and other policy rules are generally written in terms of the deviation of real output from its full
capacity level. In these equations, the output gap has been replaced with the gap between the rate of unemployment in the
longer run and its actual level (using a relationship known as Okun’s law) to represent the rules in terms of the unemployment
rate gap. The rules are implemented as responding to core PCE ination rather than to headline PCE ination because current
and near-term core ination rates tend to outperform headline ination rates as predictors of the medium-term behavior of
headline ination. Box note 6 provides references for the policy rules.
S
48 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
Although these two rules prescribe identical
policy rates over most of the period shown, including
departure from the ELB about two years before the
actual departure in December2015, one should not
conclude that they generally offer a similar degree of
policy accommodation. Had the previous economic
expansion not been cut short by the pandemic, the
balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule would likely have
continued to prescribe a lower policy rate than the
balanced-approach rule. In addition, knowledge on the
part of households and businesses that policymakers
will respond to shortfalls rather than deviations from
maximum employment can, in practice, help foster
more accommodative  nancial conditions even when
employment is below its maximum level because
nancial conditions are affected by the expected path
of the policy rate. Expectations of lower policy rates
in the future—once employment has recovered—
can reduce longer-term interest rates, support
accommodative  nancial conditions, and encourage
aggregate spending in the present. These observations
underline the importance of communication
about future policy actions and demonstrate how
a shift in focus to employment shortfalls, in the
context of a simple rule, can provide more policy
accommodation—even during times like today when
employment remains depressed.
the ELB during the pandemic-driven recession—a
constraint that helped motivate the FOMC’s other
policy actions at the time, including forward guidance
and asset purchases.
Regarding the recovery from the 2008–09 recession,
all of the simple rules shown here prescribe departure
from the ELB well before the FOMC determined
that it was appropriate to do so. The FOMC’s
judgment that it was appropriate to maintain a more
accommodative path of the federal funds rate than
prescribed by these rules was informed by a wide
range of information, including measures of labor
market conditions, indicators of in ation pressures and
in ation expectations, and readings on  nancial and
international developments.
The balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule calls for
lower policy rates than the balanced-approach rule
at times when unemployment is below its estimated
longer-run level, thus providing somewhat more policy
accommodation during the 2006–07 period and from
late 2016 until the start of the pandemic. The fact that
the policy rate prescriptions for the balanced-approach
and balanced-approach (shortfalls) rules coincide
from the 2008–09 recession up to the end of 2016
re ects the slow recovery in this period, during which
unemployment remained above real-time estimates of
its longer-run level.
Monetary Policy Rules (continued)
First-dierence rule
Taylor (1993) rule
Balanced-approach rule
Target federal funds rate
Balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule
18
15
12
9
6
3
+
_
0
3
6
Percent
202020192018201720162015201420132012201120102009200820072006
B.
Historical federal funds rate prescriptions from simple policy rules
Quarterly
Adjusted Taylor (1993) rule
N
OTE: The rules use historical values of the federal funds rate, core personal consumption expenditure ination, and the unemployment rate.
Quarterly
projections of longer-run values for the federal funds rate and the unemployment rate are derived through interpolations of the biannual
projections from Blue Chip Economic Indicators. The longer-run value for ination is taken as 2 percent.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Wolters Kluwer, Blue Chip Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
49
In conjunction with the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) meeting held on
December15–16, 2020, meeting participants
submitted their projections of the most likely
outcomes for real gross domestic product
(GDP) growth, the unemployment rate, and
ination for each year from 2020 to 2023
and over the longer run. Each participant’s
projections were based on information
available at the time of the meeting, together
with her or his assessment of appropriate
monetary policy—including a path for the
federal funds rate and its longer-run value—
and assumptions about other factors likely
to aect economic outcomes. The longer-
run projections represent each participant’s
assessment of the value to which each variable
would be expected to converge, over time,
under appropriate monetary policy and in the
absence of further shocks to the economy.
Appropriate monetary policy” is dened as
the future path of policy that each participant
deems most likely to foster outcomes for
economic activity and ination that best
satisfy his or her individual interpretation of
the statutory mandate to promote maximum
employment and price stability.
Beginning with the December2020 FOMC
meeting, all Summary of Economic
The following material was released after the conclusion of the December15–16, 2020, meeting of
the Federal Open Market Committee.
Part 3
summary of eConomiC ProjeCtions
Table 1. Economic projections of Federal Reserve Board members and Federal Reserve Bank presidents, under their
individual assumptions of projected appropriate monetary policy, December 2020
Percent
Variable
Median
1
Central tendency
2
Range
3
2020 2021 2022 2023
Longer
run
2020 2021 2022 2023
Longer
run
2020 2021 2022 2023
Longer
run
Change in real GDP ....
-2.4 4.2
3.2 2.4 1.8
-2.5-2.2 3.7–5.0
3.0–3.5 2.2–2.7 1.7–2.0
-3.3 -1.0 0.5–5.5
2.5–4.0
2.0–3.5 1.6–2.2
September projection -3.7 4.0 3.0 2.5 1.9 -4.0-3.0 3.6 4.7 2.5–3.3 2.4–3.0 1.7–2.0 -5.5–1.0 0.0–5.5 2.04.5 2.04.0 1.6–2.2
Unemployment rate ....
6.7 5.0
4.2 3.7 4.1
6.7–6.8 4.7–5.4
3.84.6 3.54.3 3.94.3
6.66.9 4.06.8
3.55.8
3.3–5.0 3.54.5
September projection 7.6 5.5 4.6 4.0 4.1 7.0–8.0 5.06.2 4.0–5.0 3.54.4 3.94.3 6.58.0 4.08.0 3.5–7.5 3.56.0 3.5 4.7
PCE ination ..........
1.2 1.8
1.9 2.0 2.0
1.2 1.7–1.9
1.8–2.0 1.92.1 2.0
1.1–1.4 1.22.3
1.5–2.2
1.72.2 2.0
September projection 1.2 1.7 1.8 2.0 2.0 1.1–1.3 1.6 –1.9 1.7–1.9 1.9–2.0 2.0 1.01.5 1.3 –2.4 1.5 –2.2 1.7–2.1 2.0
Core PCE ination
4
....
1.4 1.8
1.9 2.0
1.4 1.7–1.8
1.8–2.0 1.92.1
1.3–1.5 1.5–2.3
1.6–2.2
1.72.2
September projection
1.5 1.7
1.8 2.0
1.3–1.5 1.6 –1.8
1.7–1.9 1.9–2.0
1.2–1.6 1.5–2.4
1.6–2.2
1.72.1
Memo: Projected
appropriate policy path
Federal funds rate .....
0.1 0.1
0.1
0.1 2.5
0.1 0.1
0.1
0.1–0.4 2.3–2.5
0.1 0.1
0.1–0.4
0.1–1.1 2.0–3.0
September projection 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 2.5 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1–0.4 2.3–2.5 0.1 0.1 0.1–0.6 0.1–1.4 2.0–3.0
N: Projections of change in real gross domestic product (GDP) and projections for both measures of ination are percent changes from the fourth quarter of the previous
year to the fourth quarter of the year indicated. PCE ination and core PCE ination are the percentage rates of change in, respectively, the price index for personal consump-
tion expenditures (PCE) and the price index for PCE excluding food and energy. Projections for the unemployment rate are for the average civilian unemployment rate in the
fourth quarter of the year indicated. Each participants projections are based on his or her assessment of appropriate monetary policy. Longer-run projections represent each
participants assessment of the rate to which each variable would be expected to converge under appropriate monetary policy and in the absence of further shocks to the econ-
omy. The projections for the federal funds rate are the value of the midpoint of the projected appropriate target range for the federal funds rate or the projected appropriate
target level for the federal funds rate at the end of the specied calendar year or over the longer run. The September projections were made in conjunction with the meeting of
the Federal Open Market Committee on September 15–16, 2020. One participant did not submit longer-run projections for the change in real GDP, the unemployment rate, or
the federal funds rate in conjunction with the September 15–16, 2020, meeting, and one participant did not submit such projections in conjunction with the December 15–16,
2020, meeting.
1. For each period, the median is the middle projection when the projections are arranged from lowest to highest. When the number of projections is even, the median is the
average of the two middle projections.
2. The central tendency excludes the three highest and three lowest projections for each variable in each year.
3. The range for a variable in a given year includes all participants’ projections, from lowest to highest, for that variable in that year.
4. Longer-run projections for core PCE ination are not collected.
50 Part 3: Summary of Economic ProjEctionS
Table 2. Average historical projection error ranges
Percentage points
Variable 2020 2021 2022 2023
Change in real GDP
1
...... ±0.8 ±1.5 ±1.9 ±2.0
Unemployment rate
1
...... ±0.1 ±0.8 ±1.4 ±1.9
Total consumer prices
2
.... ±0.2 ±0.9 ±1.0 ±0.9
Short-term interest rates
3
.. ±0.1 ±1.4 ±2.0 ±2.4
N: Error ranges shown are measured as plus or minus the root mean squared
error of projections for 2000 through 2019 that were released in the winter by var-
ious private and government forecasters. As described in the box “Forecast Un-
certainty,” under certain assumptions, there is about a 70 percent probability that
actual outcomes for real GDP, unemployment, consumer prices, and the federal
funds rate will be in ranges implied by the average size of projection errors made
in the past. For more information, see David Reifschneider and Peter Tulip (2017),
“Gauging the Uncertainty of the Economic Outlook Using Historical Forecasting
Errors: The Federal Reserves Approach,” Finance and Economics Discussion
Series 2017-020 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
February), https://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2017.020.
1. Denitions of variables are in the general note to table 1.
2. Measure is the overall consumer price index, the price measure that has been
most widely used in government and private economic forecasts. Projections are
percent changes on a fourth quarter to fourth quarter basis.
3. For Federal Reserve sta forecasts, measure is the federal funds rate. For
other forecasts, measure is the rate on 3-month Treasury bills. Projection errors
are calculated using average levels, in percent, in the fourth quarter.
Projections charts and tables previously
released with the minutes of a meeting will be
released following the conclusion of an FOMC
meeting. That is, the release of the distribution
of participants’ projections (Figures 3.A.
through 3.E.), participants’ assessments of
uncertainty and risks associated with the
projections (Figures 4.A. through 4.C. and
Figure 5), and Table 2 and associated box,
which describe projection error ranges, have
been accelerated by three weeks. Two new
exhibits, Figures 4.D. and 4.E., have been
added to further enhance the information
provided on uncertainty and risks by showing
how FOMC participants’ assessments of
uncertainties and risks have evolved over time.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 51
Figure 1. Medians, centraltendencies, and rangesofeconomic projections, 2020–23 and over the longer run
−4
−3
−2
−1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Median of projections
Central tendency of projections
Range of projections
Actual
Percent
Change in real GDP
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Percent
Unemployment rate
1
2
3
Percent
PCE ination
1
2
3
Percent
Core PCE ination
Longer
run
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
Longer
run
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
Longer
run
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
Longer
run
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1. The data for the actual values of the
variables are annual.
52 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
2020 2021 2022 2023 Longer run
Percent
N: Each shaded circle indicates the value (rounded to the nearest 1/8 percentage point) of an individual participant’s
judgment of the midpoint of the appropriate target range for the federal funds rate or the appropriate target level for the federal
funds rate at the end of the specied calendar year or over the longer run. One participant did not submit longer-run projec-
tions for the federal funds rate.
Figure 2. FOMC participants’ assessments of appropriate monetary policy: Midpoint of target range or target
level for the federal funds rate
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 53
Figure 3.A. Distribution of participants’ projections for the changein real GDP, 2020–23 and overthe longer run
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
−5.8−
−5.7
−5.2−
−5.1
−4.6−
−4.5
−4.0−
−3.9
−3.4−
−3.3
−2.8−
−2.7
−2.2−
−2.1
−1.6−
−1.5
−1.0−
−0.9
−0.4−
−0.3
0.2−
0.3
0.8−
0.9
1.4−
1.5
2.0−
2.1
2.6−
2.7
3.2−
3.3
3.8−
3.9
4.4−
4.5
5.0−
5.1
Percent range
December projections
September projections
Number of participants
2020
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
−5.8−
−5.7
−5.2−
−5.1
−4.6−
−4.5
−4.0−
−3.9
−3.4−
−3.3
−2.8−
−2.7
−2.2−
−2.1
−1.6−
−1.5
−1.0−
−0.9
−0.4−
−0.3
0.2−
0.3
0.8−
0.9
1.4−
1.5
2.0−
2.1
2.6−
2.7
3.2−
3.3
3.8−
3.9
4.4−
4.5
5.0−
5.1
Percent range
Number of participants
2021
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
−5.8−
−5.7
−5.2−
−5.1
−4.6−
−4.5
−4.0−
−3.9
−3.4−
−3.3
−2.8−
−2.7
−2.2−
−2.1
−1.6−
−1.5
−1.0−
−0.9
−0.4−
−0.3
0.2−
0.3
0.8−
0.9
1.4−
1.5
2.0−
2.1
2.6−
2.7
3.2−
3.3
3.8−
3.9
4.4−
4.5
5.0−
5.1
Percent range
Number of participants
2022
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
−5.8−
−5.7
−5.2−
−5.1
−4.6−
−4.5
−4.0−
−3.9
−3.4−
−3.3
−2.8−
−2.7
−2.2−
−2.1
−1.6−
−1.5
−1.0−
−0.9
−0.4−
−0.3
0.2−
0.3
0.8−
0.9
1.4−
1.5
2.0−
2.1
2.6−
2.7
3.2−
3.3
3.8−
3.9
4.4−
4.5
5.0−
5.1
Percent range
−5.8−
−5.7
−5.2−
−5.1
−4.6−
−4.5
−4.0−
−3.9
−3.4−
−3.3
−2.8−
−2.7
−2.2−
−2.1
−1.6−
−1.5
−1.0−
−0.9
−0.4−
−0.3
0.2−
0.3
0.8−
0.9
1.4−
1.5
2.0−
2.1
2.6−
2.7
3.2−
3.3
3.8−
3.9
4.4−
4.5
5.0−
5.1
Percent range
Number of participants
2023
Number of participants
Longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
54 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Figure 3.B. Distribution of participants’ projections for the unemployment rate, 2020–23 and over the longer run
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2.8−
2.9
3.4−
3.5
4.0−
4.1
4.6−
4.7
5.2−
5.3
5.8−
5.9
6.4−
6.5
7.0−
7.1
7.6−
7.7
Percent range
December projections
September projections
Number of participants
2020
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2.8−
2.9
3.4−
3.5
4.0−
4.1
4.6−
4.7
5.2−
5.3
5.8−
5.9
6.4−
6.5
7.0−
7.1
7.6−
7.7
Percent range
Number of participants
2021
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2.8−
2.9
3.4−
3.5
4.0−
4.1
4.6−
4.7
5.2−
5.3
5.8−
5.9
6.4−
6.5
7.0−
7.1
7.6−
7.7
Percent range
Number of participants
2022
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2.8−
2.9
3.4−
3.5
4.0−
4.1
4.6−
4.7
5.2−
5.3
5.8−
5.9
6.4−
6.5
7.0−
7.1
7.6−
7.7
Percent range
Number of participants
2023
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2.8−
2.9
3.4−
3.5
4.0−
4.1
4.6−
4.7
5.2−
5.3
5.8−
5.9
6.4−
6.5
7.0−
7.1
7.6−
7.7
Percent range
Number of participants
Longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 55
Figure 3.C. Distribution of participants’ projections for PCE ination, 2020–23 and over the longer run
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
0.7−
0.8
0.9−
1.0
1.1−
1.2
1.3−
1.4
1.5−
1.6
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
Percent range
0.7−
0.8
0.9−
1.0
1.1−
1.2
1.3−
1.4
1.5−
1.6
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
Percent range
December projections
September projections
Number of participants
2020
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
2021
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
2022
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
2023
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
Longer run
0.7−
0.8
0.9−
1.0
1.1−
1.2
1.3−
1.4
1.5−
1.6
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
Percent range
0.7−
0.8
0.9−
1.0
1.1−
1.2
1.3−
1.4
1.5−
1.6
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
Percent range
0.7−
0.8
0.9−
1.0
1.1−
1.2
1.3−
1.4
1.5−
1.6
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
Percent range
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
56 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Figure 3.D. Distribution of participants’ projections for core PCEination, 2020–23
2
4
6
8
1
0
1
2
1
4
1
6
1
8
0.9−
1.0
1.1−
1.2
1.3−
1.4
1.5−
1.6
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
Percent range
Number of participants
2020
2
4
6
8
1
0
1
2
1
4
1
6
1
8
Number of participants
2021
2
4
6
8
1
0
1
2
1
4
1
6
1
8
Number of participants
2022
2
4
6
8
1
0
1
2
1
4
1
6
1
8
Number of participants
2023
December projections
September projections
0.9−
1.0
1.1−
1.2
1.3−
1.4
1.5−
1.6
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
Percent range
0.9−
1.0
1.1−
1.2
1.3−
1.4
1.5−
1.6
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
Percent range
0.9−
1.0
1.1−
1.2
1.3−
1.4
1.5−
1.6
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
Percent range
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 57
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
0.13−
0.37
0.38−
0.62
0.63−
0.87
0.88−
1.12
1.13−
1.37
1.38−
1.62
1.63−
1.87
1.88−
2.12
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
Percent range
Number of participants
2020
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
2021
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
2022
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
2023
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
Longer run
December projections
September projections
0.13−
0.37
0.38−
0.62
0.63−
0.87
0.88−
1.12
1.13−
1.37
1.38−
1.62
1.63−
1.87
1.88−
2.12
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
Percent range
0.13−
0.37
0.38−
0.62
0.63−
0.87
0.88−
1.12
1.13−
1.37
1.38−
1.62
1.63−
1.87
1.88−
2.12
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
Percent range
0.13−
0.37
0.38−
0.62
0.63−
0.87
0.88−
1.12
1.13−
1.37
1.38−
1.62
1.63−
1.87
1.88−
2.12
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
Percent range
0.13−
0.37
0.38−
0.62
0.63−
0.87
0.88−
1.12
1.13−
1.37
1.38−
1.62
1.63−
1.87
1.88−
2.12
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
Percent range
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
Figure 3.E. Distribution of participants’ judgments of the midpoint of the appropriate target range for the
feder
al funds rate or the appropriate target level for the federal funds rate, 2020–23 and over the longer run
58 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Figure 4.A. Uncertainty and risksinprojections of GDPgrowth
Median projection and condence interval basedonhistorical forecast errors
−4
−3
−2
−1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Median of projections
70% condence interval
Actual
Percent
Change in real GDP
FOMC participants’ assessments of uncertainty andrisks around their economic projections
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Lower
similar
Higher
Number of participants
Uncertainty about GDP growth
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
Number of participants
Risks to GDP growth
December projections
September projections
December projections
September projections
2015 20172016 2019 20202018 202320222021
Broadly
N
: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the percent
change in r
eal gross domestic product (GDP) from the fourth quarter of the previous year to the fourth quarter of the year
indica
ted. The condence interval around the median projected values is assumed to be symmetric and is based on root mean
squar
ed errors of various private and government forecasts made over the previous 20 years; more information about these da
ta
is a
vailable in table 2. Because current conditions may dier from those that prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years,
the width and sha
pe of the condence interval estimated on the basis of the historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC
participants’
current assessments of the uncertainty and risks around their projections; these current assessments are summa-
riz
ed in the lower panels. Generally speaking, participants who judge the uncertainty about their projections as “broadly
similar”
to the average levels of the past 20 years would view the width of the condence interval shown in the historical fan
chart as lar
gely consistent with their assessments of the uncertainty about their projections. Likewise, participants who judge
the
risks to their pr
ojections as “broadly balanced” would view the condence interval around their projections as approximately
symmetric. For denitions of uncertainty and risks in economic projections, see the box “Forecast Uncertainty.”
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 59
Figure 4.B. Uncertainty andrisks in projections of the unemployment rate
Median projection and condence interval basedonhistorical forecast errors
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Median of projections
70% condence interval
Actual
Percent
Unemployment rate
FOMC participants’ assessmentsof uncertainty and risks around their economic projections
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
Uncertainty about the unemployment rate
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
Risks to the unemployment rate
2015 20172016 2019 20202018 202320222021
December projections
September projections
December projections
September projections
Lower
similar
Higher
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
Broadly
N: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the average
civilian unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of the year indicated. The condence interval around the median projected
values is assumed to be symmetric and is based on root mean squared errors of various private and government forecasts made
over the previous 20 years; more information about these data is available in table 2. Because current conditions may dier from
those that prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the condence interval estimated on the
basis of the historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC participants’ current assessments of the uncertainty and risks
around their projections; these current assessments are summarized in the lower panels. Generally speaking, participants who
judge the uncertainty about their projections as “broadly similar” to the average levels of the past 20 years would view the wid
th
of the condence interval shown in the historical fan chart as largely consistent with their assessments of the uncertainty about
their projections. Likewise, participants who judge the risks to their projections as “broadly balanced” would view the
condence interval around their projections as approximately symmetric. For denitions of uncertainty and risks in economic
projections, see the box “Forecast Uncertainty.”
60 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Figure 4.C. Uncertainty and risksin projections of PCEination
Median projection and condence interval basedonhistorical forecasterrors
1
2
3
Median of projections
70% condence interval
Actual
Percent
PCE ination
FOMC participants’ assessments of uncertainty andrisks around their economic projections
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
Uncertainty about PCE ination
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
Risks to PCE ination
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
Uncertainty about core PCE ination
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Number of participants
Risks to core PCE ination
2015 20172016 2019 20202018 202320222021
December projections
September projections
December projections
September projections
December projections
September projections
December projections
September projections
Lower
similar
Higher
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
Broadly
Lower
similar
Higher
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
Broadly
N: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the percent
change in the price index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE) from the fourth quarter of the previous year to the
fourth quarter of the year indicated. The condence interval around the median projected values is assumed to be symmetric
and is based on root mean squared errors of various private and government forecasts made over the previous 20 years; more
information about these data is available in table 2. Because current conditions may dier from those that prevailed, on
average, over the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the condence interval estimated on the basis of the historical
forecast errors may not reect FOMC participants’ current assessments of the uncertainty and risks around their projections;
these current assessments are summarized in the lower panels. Generally speaking, participants who judge the uncertainty
about their projections as “broadly similar” to the average levels of the past 20 years would view the width of the condence
interval shown in the historical fan chart as largely consistent with their assessments of the uncertainty about their projections.
Likewise, participants who judge the risks to their projections as “broadly balanced” would view the condence interval ar
ound
their projections as approximately symmetric. For denitions of uncertainty and risks in economic projections, see the box
“Forecast Uncertainty.”
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 61
Figure 4.D. Diusion indexesof participants’ uncertainty assessments
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
Diusion index
Change in real GDP
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
Diusion index
Unemployment rate
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
Diusion index
PCE ination
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
Diusion index
Core PCE ination
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
N
: For each SEP, participants provided responses to the question “Please indicate your judgment of the uncertainty
a
ttached to your projections relative to the levels of uncertainty over the past 20 years.” Each point in the diusion indexes
r
epresents the number of participants who responded “Higher” minus the number who responded “Lower,” divided by the total
number of participants. Figure excludes March 2020 when no projections were submitted.
62 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Figure 4.E. Diusion indexesof participants’ risk weightings
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
Diusion index
Change in real GDP
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
Diusion index
Unemployment rate
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
Diusion index
PCE ination
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
Diusion index
Core PCE ination
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
N: For each SEP, participants provided responses to the question “Please indicate your judgment of the risk weighting
around your projections.” Each point in the diusion indexes represents the number of participants who responded “Weighted
to the Upside” minus the number who responded “Weighted to the Downside,” divided by the total number of participants.
Figure excludes March 2020 when no projections were submitted.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 63
Figure5. Uncertainty and risks in projectionsof the federal funds rate
0
1
2
3
4
Midpoint of target range
Median of projections
70% condence interval*
Actual
Percent
Federal funds rate
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
N: The blue and red lines are based on actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the Committee’s target
for the federal funds rate at the end of the year indicated. The actual values are the midpoint of the target range; the median
projected values are based on either the midpoint of the target range or the target level. The condence interval around the
median projected values is based on root mean squared errors of various private and government forecasts made over the
previous 20 years. The condence interval is not strictly consistent with the projections for the federal funds rate, primarily
because these projections are not forecasts of the likeliest outcomes for the federal funds rate, but rather projections of
participants’ individual assessments of appropriate monetary policy. Still, historical forecast errors provide a broad sense of the
uncertainty around the future path of the federal funds rate generated by the uncertainty about the macroeconomic variab
les as
well as additional adjustments to monetary policy that may be appropriate to onset the eects of shocks to the economy.
The condence interval is assumed to be symmetric except when it is truncated at zero - the bottom of the lowest tar
get range
for the federal funds rate that has been adopted in the past by the Committee. This truncation would not be intended to
indicate the likelihood of the use of negative interest rates to provide additional monetary policy accommodation if doing so
was judged appropriate. In such situations, the Committee could also employ other tools, including forward guidance and
large-scale asset purchases, to provide additional accommodation. Because current conditions may dier from those that
prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the condence interval estimated on the basis of the
historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC participants’ current assessments of the uncertainty and risks around their
projections.
* The condence interval is derived from forecasts of the average level of short-term interest rates in the fourth quarter of
the
year indicated; more information about these data is available in table 2. The shaded area encompasses less than a 70 percent
condence interval if the condence interval has been truncated at zero.
64 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
reported in table2 would imply a probability of about
70percent that actual GDP would expand within a
range of 2.2 to 3.8percent in the current year, 1.5 to
4.5percent in the second year, 1.1 to 4.9percent in
the third year, and 1.0 to 5.0percent in the fourth year.
The corresponding 70percent con dence intervals
for overall in ation would be 1.8 to 2.2percent in
the current year, 1.1 to 2.9percent in the second
year, 1.0 to 3.0percent in the third year, and 1.1 to
2.9percent in the fourth year. Figures 4.A through
4.C illustrate these con dence bounds in “fan charts”
that are symmetric and centered on the medians of
FOMC participants’ projections for GDP growth, the
unemployment rate, and in ation. However, in some
instances, the risks around the projections may not
be symmetric. In particular, the unemployment rate
cannot be negative; furthermore, the risks around a
particular projection might be tilted to either the upside
or the downside, in which case the corresponding fan
chart would be asymmetrically positioned around the
median projection.
Because current conditions may differ from those
that prevailed, on average, over history, participants
provide judgments as to whether the uncertainty
attached to their projections of each economic variable
is greater than, smaller than, or broadly similar to
typical levels of forecast uncertainty seen in the past
20years, as presented in table2 and re ected in
the widths of the con dence intervals shown in the
top panels of  gures 4.A through 4.C. Participants’
The economic projections provided by the members
of the Board of Governors and the presidents of
the Federal Reserve Banks inform discussions of
monetary policy among policymakers and can aid
public understanding of the basis for policy actions.
Considerable uncertainty attends these projections,
however. The economic and statistical models and
relationships used to help produce economic forecasts
are necessarily imperfect descriptions of the real world,
and the future path of the economy can be affected
by myriad unforeseen developments and events. Thus,
in setting the stance of monetary policy, participants
consider not only what appears to be the most likely
economic outcome as embodied in their projections,
but also the range of alternative possibilities, the
likelihood of their occurring, and the potential costs to
the economy should they occur.
Table 2 summarizes the average historical accuracy
of a range of forecasts, including those reported in
past Monetary Policy Reports and those prepared
by the Federal Reserve Board’s staff in advance of
meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC). The projection error ranges shown in the
table illustrate the considerable uncertainty associated
with economic forecasts. For example, suppose a
participant projects that real gross domestic product
(GDP) and total consumer prices will rise steadily at
annual rates of, respectively, 3percent and 2percent.
If the uncertainty attending those projections is similar
to that experienced in the past and the risks around
the projections are broadly balanced, the numbers
Forecast Uncertainty
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: FEBRUARY 2021 65
rather are projections of participants’ individual
assessments of appropriate monetary policy and are
on an end-of-year basis. However, the forecast errors
should provide a sense of the uncertainty around the
future path of the federal funds rate generated by the
uncertainty about the macroeconomic variables as
well as additional adjustments to monetary policy that
would be appropriate to offset the effects of shocks to
the economy.
If at some point in the future the con dence interval
around the federal funds rate were to extend below
zero, it would be truncated at zero for purposes of
the fan chart shown in  gure5; zero is the bottom of
the lowest target range for the federal funds rate that
has been adopted by the Committee in the past. This
approach to the construction of the federal funds rate
fan chart would be merely a convention; it would
not have any implications for possible future policy
decisions regarding the use of negative interest rates to
provide additional monetary policy accommodation
if doing so were appropriate. In such situations, the
Committee could also employ other tools, including
forward guidance and asset purchases, to provide
additional accommodation.
While  gures 4.A through 4.C provide information
on the uncertainty around the economic projections,
gure1 provides information on the range of views
across FOMC participants. A comparison of  gure1
with  gures 4.A through 4.C shows that the dispersion
of the projections across participants is much smaller
than the average forecast errors over the past 20years.
current assessments of the uncertainty surrounding
their projections are summarized in the bottom-left
panels of those  gures. Participants also provide
judgments as to whether the risks to their projections
are weighted to the upside, are weighted to the
downside, or are broadly balanced. That is, while
the symmetric historical fan charts shown in the top
panels of  gures 4.A through 4.C imply that the risks to
participants’ projections are balanced, participants may
judge that there is a greater risk that a given variable
will be above rather than below their projections. These
judgments are summarized in the lower-right panels of
gures 4.A through 4.C.
As with real activity and in ation, the outlook
for the future path of the federal funds rate is subject
to considerable uncertainty. This uncertainty arises
primarily because each participant’s assessment of
the appropriate stance of monetary policy depends
importantly on the evolution of real activity and
in ation over time. If economic conditions evolve
in an unexpected manner, then assessments of the
appropriate setting of the federal funds rate would
change from that point forward. The  nal line in
table2 shows the error ranges for forecasts of short-
term interest rates. They suggest that the historical
con dence intervals associated with projections
of the federal funds rate are quite wide. It should
be noted, however, that these con dence intervals
are not strictly consistent with the projections for
the federal funds rate, as these projections are not
forecasts of the most likely quarterly outcomes but
67
AFE advanced foreign economy
BLS Bureau of Labor Statistics
CARES Act Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security Act
CES Current Employment Statistics
C&I commercial and industrial
COVID-19 coronavirus disease 2019
CPFF Commercial Paper Funding Facility
CPI consumer price index
DPI disposable personal income
ELB eective lower bound
EME emerging market economy
EPOP ratio employment-to-population ratio
FIMA Foreign and International Monetary Authorities
FOMC Federal Open Market Committee; also, the Committee
GDP gross domestic product
G-SIBs global systemically important banks
LFPR labor force participation rate
Main Street Main Street Lending Program
MBS mortgage-backed securities
MMLF Money Market Mutual Fund Lending Facility
OPEC Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries
PCE personal consumption expenditures
PDCF Primary Dealer Credit Facility
PPPLF Paycheck Protection Program Liquidity Facility
QSS Quarterly Services Survey
repo repurchase agreement
RRE residential real estate
SBA Small Business Administration
SEP Summary of Economic Projections
TIPS Treasury Ination-Protected Securities
VIX implied volatility for the S&P 500 index
abbreviations
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
For use at 11:00 a.m. EST
February 19, 2021
Monetary Policy rePort
February 19, 2021