ISBN 978-1-869457-17-4
Project no. 13.03/16462
Public Version
Mobile Market Study Findings
The Commission:
Dr Stephen Gale
Dr Jill Walker
Elisabeth Welson
John Crawford
Date of publication:
26 September 2019
2
Associated documents
Publication
date
Reference
Title
6 October 2017
Mobile Market Study - Terms of
Reference
27 March 2018
Mobile Market Study Scope paper
31 August 2018
Study of Mobile Telecommunications
Markets in New Zealand - Issues Paper
16 May 2019
Mobile Market Study Preliminary
Findings
16 May 2019
Red Dawn Consulting Global Mobile
Industry Trends: Implications for
New Zealand
16 May 2019
Red Dawn Consulting MVNO
Landscape: Global perspectives and
New Zealand Applications
16 May 2019
Behavioural Insights Team Behavioural
Biases in Telecommunications: A review
for the Commerce Commission
Commerce Commission
Wellington, New Zealand
3
4
Glossary
Acronym
Title
2G
2nd Generation mobile communications technology
3G
3rd Generation mobile communications technology
4G
4th Generation mobile communications technology
5G
5th Generation mobile communications technology
ACCC
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission
ARPU
Average Revenue per month per User/subscriber
Backhaul
In a telecommunications network, backhaul is the capacity between
the core backbone network and the local edge networks
BEREC
Body of European Regulators for Electronic Communications
CDMA
Code-Division Multiple Access a 2G mobile phone standard
developed in the United States
CDR
Consumer Data Right typically a data portability right, whereby a
consumer can easily provide a standardised set of their usage
information to a potential provider
Commerce Act
The Commerce Act 1986
DFAS
Direct Fibre Access Service defined in section 164 of the
Telecommunications Act. Typically used in mobile networks for
dedicated backhaul services
EBITDA
An accounting term Earnings Before Interest, Tax, Depreciation
and Amortisation
eSIMs
Embedded SIM a non-removable version of a SIM card
Ethernet
A family of computer networking technologies most commonly
used in wired Local Area Networks and Wide Area Networks
GB
Gigabyte. 1 gigabyte = 1024 megabytes
GCSB
(NZ) Government Communications Security Bureau
GHz
Gigahertz. 1 gigahertz = 1000 megahertz
GSM
Global System for Mobile communications a standard developed
to describe the protocols for 2G digital cellular networks
GSMA
Global System for Mobile Communication Association trade body
that represents the interests of mobile network operators
worldwide
IoT
Internet of Things the network of physical and virtual objects
accessed through the internet (such as smart sensors and smart
meters)
5
IP
Internet Protocol the method or protocol by which data is sent
from one computer to another on the internet. Each computer
(host) on the internet has at least one IP address that uniquely
identifies it from all other computers on the internet
LFC
Local Fibre Company provider of fibre access services under the
NZ Governments UFB initiative (see section 156AB of the
Telecommunications Act)
LTE
Long Term Evolution a name given to the fourth generation of
mobile technology that can provide high speed mobile broadband
MBIE
Ministry of Business Innovation and Employment
MBSF
Mobile Black Spot Fund Government fund to provide greater
mobile coverage on state highways and in tourism locations where
no coverage currently exists
MHz
Megahertz one million oscillations per second
MNO
Mobile Network Operator an operator that owns or controls all
the elements necessary to deliver mobile services to consumers,
including radio spectrum and the wireless network infrastructure
MTAS
Mobile Termination Access Service a regulated service that
provides for the termination on a cellular mobile telephone
network of voice calls and SMS messages
MTR
Mobile Termination Rates the wholesale prices for the MTAS
MVNE
Mobile Virtual Network Enabler a company that provides the
platforms to keep pace with rapidly evolving consumer demand for
services. They also allow rapid on-boarding and integration of an
MVNO with an MNO and provide the ability to connect with third
parties via defined IT systems
MVNO
Mobile Virtual Network Operator an operator that provides
mobile services but does not generally have its own radio spectrum
or much of the infrastructure required to provide mobile services. It
therefore relies on buying services from an MNO. The amount of
control it has over the services it offers will vary according to the
nature of its agreement
NERA
NERA Economic Consulting
OECD
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development
Ofcom
Office of Communications the regulatory and competition
authority for broadcasting, telecommunications and postal
industries in the United Kingdom
OTT
Over the top refers to content and applications provided from a
third party and delivered to an end user device, leaving the retailer
responsible only for transporting IP packets
6
RBI (and RBI2)
Rural Broadband Initiative an initiative where the Government
partners with private sector telecommunications operators to
upgrade or extend telecommunications networks outside UFB areas
RCG
Rural Connectivity Group a joint venture between 2degrees,
Spark and Vodafone who have a contract with the Government
under RBI2 and the MBSF
RSP
Retail Service Provider RSPs provide telecommunications services
to consumers
RSM
Radio Spectrum Management business unit of MBIE responsible
for managing radio spectrum
RTP
Restrictive Trade Practices
SIM
Subscriber Identity Module card commonly known as a SIM card
that contains a microchip that stores data that identifies the user,
for use in GSM and compatible 3G and 4G mobile phones
SMS
Short Message Service commonly known as a text messaging, this
is a service for sending and receiving short messages between
mobile devices
STD
Standard Terms Determination the Commerce Commission’s
primary mechanism for regulating non-fibre telecommunications
services under the Telecommunications Act by determining the
terms on which a designated access service or specified service
must be supplied
Telecommunications
Act
The Telecommunications Act 2001
UFB
The New Zealand Government's Ultra-Fast Broadband initiative
UMTS
Universal Mobile Telecommunications System the 3G successor
to the 2G GSM standard, which allows voice telephony, mobile
internet access, fixed wireless internet access, video calls and
mobile TV
WiFi
Wireless Fidelity Standard a series of standards for a popular
technology that allows electronic devices to exchange data
wirelessly (using radio waves), including allowing mobile devices to
connect to high speed internet connections
WISPA NZ
Wireless Internet Service Providers Association of New Zealand Inc
an association of Wireless Internet Services Providers (WISPs)
that typically service rural locations in New Zealand where mobile
networks currently do not operate, or have limited coverage
7
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Glossary 4
Executive summary and findings 9
Mobile services market study 9
Competition in the mobile market 9
Findings from our study of the mobile services market 10
Chapter 1 Introduction 16
Purpose of the study and legal framework 16
Purpose of the study 16
Legal framework for the study 17
Timeline of the study 17
Purpose and structure of the Findings report 18
Chapter 2 Mobile networks and services 20
Purpose of this chapter 20
Mobile networks 20
Mobile services 22
Mobile service providers 25
Mobile regulatory settings in New Zealand 26
Changes to regulation 27
Chapter 3 Development of mobile services and competition 28
Purpose and structure of this chapter 28
Purpose 28
Structure 28
Analysis of the mobile market 28
Market structure and market shares 29
Bundling 34
Pricing 36
Usage trends 46
Investment 48
Profitability 50
Quality of mobile services 52
Consumer satisfaction 54
Our views on the key issues in the mobile market 57
Spectrum 57
MVNOs 58
Consumer engagement 59
Chapter 4 Key issues we identified 60
Purpose and structure of this chapter 60
Spectrum 60
Introduction 60
Spectrum and competition between existing MNOs 60
Spectrum and new entry 66
Other obligations and payment terms for spectrum allocation 69
8
MVNOs 72
Introduction 72
Potential benefits to consumers from MVNOs 72
MVNO operating models and margins 75
Emerging competition at the wholesale level 77
Consumer engagement and experience with mobile services 85
Introduction 85
How easily can consumers access the information they need? 85
How easily can consumers assess the information they have? 86
How easy is it for consumers to act? 90
Behavioural biases 94
Potential remedies/actions 96
Chapter 5 State of competition in the mobile market 100
Purpose and structure of this chapter 100
Purpose 100
Structure 100
Our view on the state of competition in the mobile market 100
Existing competition 100
Conditions for further expansion and entry 104
Consumer engagement 106
Chapter 6 Future developments in mobile services 109
Purpose of this chapter 109
5G mobile networks 109
eSIMs 112
Network slicing 114
Infrastructure sharing 115
Chapter 7 Regulated services 119
Purpose of this chapter 119
Mobile termination access services 119
National roaming 122
Mobile co-location 123
Number portability 125
Backhaul 125
9
Executive summary and findings
Mobile services market study
X1 Mobile communications have developed into an essential function, supporting
New Zealanders in all aspects of their lives. Mobile services allow consumers to
contact friends and family, conduct business, be entertained, and engage with
Government, medical, educational and emergency services when not connected to a
fixed network. The importance of mobile communications is expected to increase
even further in the future with the continued growth of machine-to-machine
communications and the internet of things (IoT).
X2 Rapid technological change is a hallmark of the telecommunications sector,
particularly in markets in which mobile services are supplied. Non-traditional
network providers and over the top (OTT) suppliers such as Google and Apple add to
the challenges for regulatory authorities and policy makers seeking to ensure that
the competition and regulatory policy settings are appropriate.
X3 One of our mandates under the Telecommunications Act 2001 (Telecommunications
Act) is to monitor competition, and the performance and development of,
telecommunication markets. In this study we have analysed the current state of
competition for mobile services, likely future developments, and the potential
impacts on competition and consumers. This analysis included examining issues of
how the supply of mobile services has performed, barriers to entry and expansion,
and the extent to which consumers of mobile services are engaged and can take
advantage of competing retail offers.
Competition in the mobile market
X4 Three vertically integrated national mobile network operators (MNOs) - 2degrees,
Vodafone and Spark - provide retail mobile services to New Zealand consumers.
Alongside these MNOs are a small number of mobile service providers that operate
solely at the retail level as mobile virtual network operators (MVNOs). These
retail-only mobile operators include the Vocus brands and the Warehouse, as well as
sub-brands like Spark’s Skinny mobile. Kogan Mobile has also recently launched
mobile services in New Zealand. This compares with ten years ago when there were
only two vertically integrated national MNOs and a small number of MVNOs and no
MNO sub-brands.
X5 Increased competition has contributed to improved outcomes for consumers
through lower prices, increasing quality, and greater choice of services. Most key
indicators like pricing, quality of service, coverage, and choice are trending in a
positive direction.
10
X6 During our study, we identified spectrum, MVNOs and consumer engagement as
important factors likely to influence the further development of competition in the
mobile market going forward.
Findings from our study of the mobile services market
X7 In this section we set out our consolidated findings and our actions arising from our
study into the mobile market.
X8 Table X1 sets out our general findings on the current state of the mobile market.
Table X1 Findings on the development of the mobile market
Finding
number
Finding
F1
Market shares among the three national MNOs have become more evenly
balanced over time, particularly in the prepaid and residential on-account
segments.
F2
Ongoing investment in the mobile networks has seen all three MNOs investing
in new generations of mobile technology and 2degrees completing the roll-out
of its national network.
F3
All three national MNOs are reporting profits, although profit margins vary,
reflecting differences in market share and mix of customers.
F4
The three national MNOs appear to perform well on most technical measures
of quality, although there is some evidence that the quality of coverage for 4G
services (as measured by availability) may be relatively low compared to other
countries.
F5
Prices of mobile services have been falling. Prices for low and medium usage
bundles compare well with other OECD countries. Prices for higher usage
bundles remain relatively expensive, especially when compared with Australia,
although recent market developments have resulted in ongoing innovation
and improved value for consumers in relation to higher usage bundles.
F6
Usage of mobile calls and in particular mobile data has continued to increase in
recent years, with the amount of mobile data used per subscriber more than
doubling over the last two years. Although average usage of mobile data
appears to be relatively low compared to other countries, this may be due to a
number of factors, including pricing of higher usage bundles and the
availability and quality of fixed networks (including WiFi hotspots) in
New Zealand.
11
X9 Tables X2, X3 and X4 set out our findings on the key issues of spectrum allocation,
MVNOs, and consumer engagement.
Table X2 Findings on spectrum
Finding
number
Finding
F7
Spectrum is a scarce and critical input into the supply of mobile services.
Significant asymmetries in spectrum holdings (including in terms of the
amount and type of spectrum held) can affect competition in the mobile
market. The design of future allocation processes for spectrum should have
regard to such asymmetries. In setting limits on the amount of spectrum that
may be acquired, it may also be appropriate to have regard to existing holdings
in other bands which represent a substitute for the spectrum being auctioned
or allocated.
F8
We do not believe there is a case for regulatory intervention to promote a
fourth national MNO to enter the market. However, the design of the
upcoming 3.5 GHz spectrum allocation process should not preclude new
parties (including parties who may complement or compete with the existing
MNOs) from obtaining spectrum.
F9
We do not believe that there is a strong case for including a condition on
spectrum rights that requires wholesale access to be offered to third parties.
Table X3 Findings on MVNOs
Finding
number
Finding
F10
Until recently, wholesale competition between MNOs to host MVNOs has
been limited. MVNOs currently serve just over 1% of the retail mobile market,
although there is some evidence that increased wholesale activity by 2degrees
has prompted a response from Spark and Vodafone in offering MVNO access.
New commercial MVNO agreements have been signed during the past 18
months, such as those between Trustpower and Spark, and Kogan Mobile and
Vodafone.
12
F11
With three national mobile networks, sufficient competitive conditions at the
wholesale level exist and we expect MVNOs should emerge if they are
commercially viable. The commercial viability of an MVNO will in part depend
on the terms agreed with the host MNO. Based on the evidence that we have
seen and the entry expected (as noted in F10), competition at the wholesale
level has improved. However, spectrum allocation decisions will be critical to
support this competition.
F12
In light of this, we do not consider MVNO access regulation to be appropriate
at this time. There would need to be greater evidence of market failure in
respect of outcomes delivered to mobile consumers to justify wholesale access
regulation. We intend to monitor the development of MVNOs, including the
commercial terms being offered by the MNOs.
Table X4 Findings on consumer engagement
Finding
number
Finding
F13
Most consumers can easily access their mobile usage information, but
information on mobile performance (speeds, actual quality of coverage etc) is
harder to access.
F14
Most consumers find it easy to compare available plans, but report that they
only do so infrequently.
F15
Our evidence shows that the process for residential consumers to switch
between mobile suppliers is relatively easy, given that:
a) mobile number portability is available;
b) there are low numbers of locked handsets; and
c) long-term contracts for residential consumers are not prominent.
Bundling of mobile and fixed-line services, which can increase customer
stickiness, does not appear to be widespread in the residential market.
F16
While residential consumers report being able to easily access usage
information and compare plans, and that the process of switching appears to
be relatively easy, a significant proportion of consumers have not compared
plans in the last 12 months and have remained with their current supplier for
more than five years. This suggests that there is a degree of consumer inertia,
and we have commenced an analysis of mobile bills to shed light on whether
this is cause for concern.
13
F17
Switching in the business market appears to be more complex and more
infrequent than residential mobile services. Businesses typically purchase
mobile and fixed services as a package, often through fixed-term contracts,
with brand reputation being an important driver. Larger business customers
are more sophisticated buyers, generally have more access to specialist advice
and support, and are more likely to have dedicated procurement resources.
X10 A summary of our findings on the state of competition and our actions is set out in
table X5 and table X6 below.
Table X5 Findings on the state of competition
Finding
number
Finding
F18
Our view is that competition in the retail mobile market has become more
established with three independent, national network-based competitors. This
has resulted in mobile consumers benefitting from an increasingly competitive
market environment.
F19
There remain some areas where we anticipate competitive outcomes for
consumers could improve further, such as pricing for higher usage bundles of
mobile services (although recent market developments have improved
consumer outcomes for higher usage bundles). Average mobile data usage in
New Zealand remains low by international standards, which may be due to a
number of factors, including pricing of higher usage bundles and the
availability and quality of fixed networks (including WiFi hotspots) in
New Zealand.
F20
We believe that the conditions for effective competition exist, with the three
MNOs each having a network of similar technology with similar geographic and
population coverage metrics. We consider that:
a) spectrum must be allocated with wholesale and retail competition
matters at the forefront of decisions;
b) with the pre-conditions for competition in place and the adequate
allocation of spectrum, we would expect MVNO services to
continue to develop where market opportunities exist; and
c) there may be room for improved consumer engagement, to
ensure that consumers are aware of and able to easily take
advantage of competing offers to drive competition.
14
Table X6 Actions on the state of competition
Action
number
Action
A1
We will continue to engage with MBIE on the importance of the upcoming
spectrum allocation/auctions for delivering competitive outcomes in the
mobile market.
A2
We have amended the annual monitoring questionnaire to capture
information on the development of MVNO market share and business
sustainability. We also intend to periodically review commercial MVNO
arrangements. This will provide us with greater ongoing visibility of the terms
being offered to MVNOs, and how the commercial terms compare to key price
and non-price dimensions of MVNO access.
A3
We will undertake further work as part of our wider responsibilities under
section 9A and Part 7 of the Telecommunications Act (outside of this study) to:
a) improve our understanding of the extent to which consumers can
and do access, assess and act on relevant information in the
mobile and wider telecommunications markets;
b) assess consumers choices of mobile plans against their usage,
including quantification of the potential savings mobile consumers
could make if they were on plans that better match their usage;
and
c) assess the quality of services provided by mobile suppliers and the
extent to which consumers are actively engaged in the mobile
market, as part of our wider retail service quality programme,
including our ability to review or create retail service quality codes
if appropriate.
15
X11 In table X7 we summarise our findings on some of the potential future
developments that may affect competition.
Table X7 Findings on future developments in the mobile market
Finding
number
Finding
F21
5G will initially be an evolution over existing networks, and over time network
densification will occur. Investment in 5G may alter the economics of mobile
provision and raises the prospect of greater infrastructure sharing, and larger
incentives to utilise network capacity through MVNO agreements.
F22
eSIM capable devices are likely to become more prevalent, with the potential
to reduce switching costs for both consumers, MNOs and MVNOs. However,
there is the potential for competition to be suppressed if MNOs do not enable
eSIMs or lock eSIM devices to their network.
F23
We may see more infrastructure sharing. Whether this enhances or suppresses
competition will depend on how the arrangements are structured. We would
expect to see infrastructure sharing proposals that raise potential competition
concerns come to us for authorisation.
X12 In table X8 we set out our findings on regulated services and our planned reviews of
those services over the next five years.
Table X8 Findings on regulated services
Finding
number
Finding
F24
Our review of the current market conditions, and likely future developments,
has not identified sufficient grounds for us to bring forward our planned
reviews of regulated services. The scheduled reviews for these services are set
out in Table 1 in Chapter 2.
F25
Backhaul services, whether metropolitan or between national network nodes,
appear not to have constrained the competitiveness or development of mobile
services, to date. However, we recognise the potential for bottlenecks to
develop as mobile (eg, 5G), fibre technologies (eg, passive optical networking)
and fibre regulation undergo a period of significant change.
16
Chapter 1 Introduction
Purpose of the study and legal framework
Purpose of the study
1.1 We have undertaken this study of mobile markets in New Zealand (study) to gain a
better understanding of how the mobile market is currently performing and
developing, and to consider how the mobile landscape may evolve in the future.
1
1.2 The mobile market study has helped us to:
build an evidence base, so we can track relevant trends and identify
whether there are any current or potential barriers to competition
delivering benefits for consumers of mobile services in New Zealand;
ensure that any future market interventions, if required, will be
appropriate and proportionate;
identify areas in the mobile market that might require more or less focus
on an ongoing basis;
inform policy makers, industry and consumers of the performance of the
mobile market through regular monitoring and reporting of market
performance and development;
consider whether any regulatory measures (including deregulation) may
be appropriate;
consider whether to recommend legislative changes; and
consider whether any investigations into potential breaches of the Fair
Trading Act 1986, Part 2 of the Commerce Act 1986 (Commerce Act) or
Credit Contracts and Consumer Finance Act 2003 may be required.
1
Throughout this document we refer to the market in which mobile services are supplied. We do not
consider that a formal definition of the dimensions of the relevant market or markets (as might be
undertaken for the purposes of Part 2 or Part 3 of the Commerce Act) is required for this study.
17
Legal framework for the study
1.3 We have conducted this study under section 9A of the Telecommunications Act.
Section 9A sets out that:
2
(1) In addition to the other functions conferred on the Commission by this Act, the
Commission-
(a) must monitor competition in telecommunications markets and the
performance and development of telecommunications markets; and
(b) may conduct inquiries, reviews, and studies (including international
benchmarking) into any matter relating to the telecommunications industry or
the long-term benefit of end-users of telecommunications services within New
Zealand; and
(c) must monitor compliance with the Commission 111 contact code; and
(d) must make available reports, summaries, and information about the things
referred to in paragraphs (a) to (c); and
(e) must monitor retail service quality in relation to telecommunications services;
and
(f) must make available reports, summaries, and information about retail service
quality in a way that informs consumer choice.
(2) The functions in subsection (1)(d) and (f) do not require the Commission to release
all documents that the Commission produces or acquires under this section or
section 10A.
1.4 One of the ways we use section 9A studies is to gather information about, and
develop our understanding of, telecommunications markets.
Timeline of the study
1.5 On 6 October 2017, we announced this study of mobile markets in New Zealand
and invited interested parties to submit on our proposed Terms of Reference for
the study.
3
1.6 We received submissions from 2degrees, Blue Reach, Chorus, InternetNZ, New
Street Research, Spark, Trustpower, Vocus, Vodafone and the Wireless Internet
Service Providers Association of New Zealand (WISPA NZ). Public versions of the
submissions are available on our website.
2
The former section 9A was replaced on 13 November 2018 pursuant to section 25 of the
Telecommunications (New Regulatory Framework) Amendment Act 2018 (2018 No 48). The replacement
section 9A included new sections 9A(1)(e) and (f). The addition of these two clauses in section 9A did not
affect this study.
3
Commerce Commission website, “Mobile market study”, https://comcom.govt.nz/regulated-
industries/telecommunications/projects/mobile-market-study.
18
1.7 Following the submissions on the Terms of Reference, we published our scope
paper on 27 March 2018, and indicated that we would publish an Issues Paper and
seek submissions.
1.8 We published our Issues Paper on 31 August 2018, and received submissions from
2degrees, Chorus, InternetNZ, Spark, Trustpower, Speedchecker Ltd, Venture
Southland, Vocus, Vodafone and WISPA NZ . Public versions of the submissions are
available on our website.
1.9 We published our Preliminary Findings paper on 16 May 2019, and received
submissions from 2degrees, BAINZ Consulting, Chorus, InternetNZ, Nova, Sky,
Spark, Trustpower, TUANZ, Vocus, and Vodafone. We also received cross-
submissions from 2degrees, Chorus, Spark, Trustpower, Vocus, and Vodafone.
Purpose and structure of the Findings report
Purpose of the report
1.10 In this report, we present our findings and actions from our analysis of the
performance and development of the mobile market. It also considers emerging
trends and their potential impact on competition and market outcomes.
1.11 In preparing our findings, we have considered the submissions received in response
to our Terms of Reference, Issues Paper, and Preliminary Findings paper, as well as
information gathered from stakeholders, analysis from independent consultants,
and other information that we have referenced throughout this paper.
Structure of the report
1.12 Chapter 2 provides background on mobile networks and services, and the
regulatory settings that currently apply to the mobile market.
1.13 Chapter 3 describes the development of mobile services and competition using the
following range of competition indicators:
market structure and market shares, including by market segment;
bundling of mobile services with other services;
pricing, including how prices for mobile services have moved over time,
and how prices in New Zealand compare to prices in other countries;
usage trends, including how volumes of mobile calls, messaging services,
and mobile data have changed over time, and the importance of mobile
services to consumers;
investment in mobile access infrastructure and spectrum;
19
profitability of mobile suppliers;
quality of mobile services, including network coverage, availability, mobile
data speeds, and customer service; and
consumer satisfaction.
1.14 Chapter 4 sets out a detailed exploration of three key issues we identified that may
have an influence on delivering competitive outcomes for mobile consumers in
New Zealand. These are:
spectrum the allocation of, or access to, adequate spectrum is an
important issue to sustain competition and to accommodate rapidly
growing demand for mobile services;
MVNO access the competitive conditions for the provision of wholesale
mobile services; and
consumer engagement the ability of consumers to make informed
decisions and their willingness to take advantage of competition between
suppliers of mobile services. Consumer engagement is important for
driving competition and facilitating entry and expansion.
1.15 Chapter 5 sets out our views on the state of competition in the mobile market,
having considered the performance of the mobile market in New Zealand to date
and the key issues which are likely to influence the further development of
competition in the mobile market going forward.
1.16 Chapter 6 discusses a selection of potential developments which may be relevant
to future mobile competition and consumers.
1.17 Chapter 7 sets out our examination of our regulatory settings and services in light
of the performance and potential evolution of mobile services.
20
Chapter 2 Mobile networks and services
Purpose of this chapter
2.1 This chapter introduces and briefly describes the services within the scope of our
study. We discuss the components of a generic mobile telecommunications
network and the services that are supplied over it.
2.2 We distinguish between mobile services (where the signal connecting consumer
devices is handed over between cell sites as the consumer moves around) and fixed
wireless services (which are more location-specific).
2.3 We also summarise the different types of providers of mobile services and briefly
outline the current regulatory framework.
Mobile networks
2.4 A mobile network (or a cellular network) is a communications network where the
device is linked to a cell site by a wireless connection. Figure 1 illustrates the key
elements of a mobile network.
Figure 1 Mobile network
2.5 In a mobile network, the overall area covered by the network is divided up into
smaller areas called cells. Each cell is served by a fixed transmitter and receiver
called a base station, which is located at the cell site. User devices such as cell
phones or wireless routers use the base stations to communicate over the cellular
network.
2.6 Mobile services and mobile network architectures have undergone significant
evolution since mobile networks were first deployed. Depending on the specific
21
region of the world, different sets of standards were adopted for each network
generation.
In Europe and most of the world, the Global System for Mobile (GSM)
standard was used for the second generation (2G) of mobile systems. This
later evolved to the Universal Mobile Telecommunications System (UMTS)
for the third generation (3G) and Long Term Evolution (LTE) for 4G.
In the USA, the CDMAOne standard became the dominant 2G system
which later evolved to CDMA2000 for 3G and LTE for 4G.
2.7 New Zealand MNOs currently use the GSM, UMTS and LTE systems for their 2G, 3G
and 4G networks respectively. Most mobile services in New Zealand use 3G or 4G
networks, with 2G either already decommissioned or being progressively phased
out. Vodafone has recently announced that it will launch a 5G network in
December 2019 in parts of Auckland, Wellington, Christchurch, and Queenstown.
4
2.8 Radio spectrum is a critical input to the deployment of a mobile network. It refers
to the radio frequencies allocated to the mobile industry and other sectors for
communication over-the-air.
2.9 MNOs use a variety of spectrum bands to provide mobile services. Lower spectrum
frequencies provide wider coverage and have better penetration (meaning they are
better able to pass through objects such as walls) than higher spectrum
frequencies. MNOs will use higher spectrum frequencies if they have exhausted the
lower ones or need more capacity.
2.10 This has meant that MNOs typically use lower spectrum frequencies to serve rural
locations, where coverage rather than capacity is a concern. Conversely, in urban
areas where capacity (rather than coverage) is a concern, MNOs typically use
higher frequency spectrum.
2.11 Backhaul (transport) is a generic term used to describe a point to point service
where aggregated traffic is carried between different points (‘nodes’) in a network.
In a mobile network, the MNO uses backhaul to connect its cell sites to other
aggregation nodes such as mobile switching centres. Backhaul contributes to the
service performance that an MNO’s customers receive as it impacts on the capacity
of the network and the latency of mobile services provided.
5
4
See https://news.vodafone.co.nz/article/vodafone-5g-launch-marks-day-one-new-ownership.
5
Latency represents the reaction time of a network. It measures the time it takes for an end user’s device
to receive a response to a request.
22
2.12 The MNO may deploy its own backhaul infrastructure or may purchase backhaul
from third parties. The backhaul requirements of a mobile network are typically
based on fibre to ensure service performance levels, however wireless backhaul
(digital microwave links) may be used in locations where fibre build out is
prohibitively expensive, traffic is low and spectrum interference is not an issue.
2.13 Mobile networks interconnect with one another (and fixed networks) so that
subscribers on one network are able to communicate with subscribers on other
networks.
2.14 Mobile networks can also provide connectivity to IoT devices such as smart sensors
(to measure, for example, temperature or motion) and smart meters (to measure,
for example, electricity usage). IoT describes the network of physical and virtual
objects accessed through the internet.
6
Mobile services
2.15 Mobile services are communications services (voice, messaging, and data) which
remain available to subscribers as they move around. Mobile services are delivered
over a cellular mobile network to devices such as mobile handsets, or data devices
such as tablets with in-built mobile connectivity, or ‘dongle’ devices using cellular
modems (Figure 2). These devices contain a subscriber identity module (SIM) card,
which authenticates the subscriber and allows them to connect to their chosen
network.
Figure 2 Mobile devices
2.16 Mobile networks were initially designed to carry voice and messaging services. The
emergence of 3G and, in particular, 4G mobile network technologies has made the
6
IoT devices can be connected via a mobile network or a specialised IoT network.
23
delivery of mobile data services at least as important as voice and messaging,
providing for mobile broadband connectivity and OTT services.
2.17 These services are mobile in the sense that they can be used while moving around
and are not tied to a specific fixed location of the consumer’s device. As a
consumer moves from the coverage area of one cell site to that of a neighbouring
cell site, the signal to their mobile device is handed over between cell sites.
2.18 Mobile services are different to voice and broadband services that are delivered to
a fixed location, including fixed-line services (delivered over copper, coaxial cable or
fibre-based networks) and ‘fixed wireless’ services (delivered over a wireless
network). These fixed-line and fixed wireless services typically offer a local WiFi
connection to devices and enable mobile devices to use fixed-line data allowances
(which are often unlimited) rather than mobile data.
2.19 From a consumer’s perspective, a fixed wireless modem looks similar to a fixed-line
modem. In both cases, consumers’ devices are connected either through local WiFi
or an Ethernet cable. The main difference is that behind the fixed wireless modem,
the network connection is via a wireless network rather than a copper or fibre
cable.
2.20 In our 2016 review of the Schedule 1 services,
7
we noted that fixed wireless
services provide similar functionality and features as a fixed-line broadband service
at similar prices. We also found that mobile broadband services were considerably
more expensive on a price per gigabyte (GB) basis than fixed wireless and fixed-line
broadband services, and that the average amount of data usage was considerably
higher for fixed broadband services than for mobile broadband. This remains the
case. For example, Spark offers entry-level fibre and fixed wireless broadband
services for the same retail price ($75 per month for up to 120GB, or $0.63 per GB).
By comparison, Spark offers mobile broadband for $69.99 for 12GB ($5.83 per GB).
8
2.21 The performance of broadband services delivered over different fixed-line and
wireless network technologies varies, as shown in our Measuring Broadband
New Zealand report.
9
This suggests that fixed wireless services are currently
competing with other fixed-line services in New Zealand, and in particular with
7
Commerce Commission, “Review of Designated and Specified Services under Schedule 1 of the
Telecommunications Act 2001”, (5 July 2016), para A24. The review considered 14 services, including
mobile co-location and number portability, both relevant to mobile services. The process for reviewing
Schedule 1 services is discussed further at para 2.42 below.
8
Spark website accessed September 2019.
9
Commerce Commission and SamKnows, “Measuring Broadband New Zealand”, (13 June 2019).
24
DSL-based services.
10
Mobile broadband services are likely to have a more
complementary relationship at this stage.
11
2.22 Although we do not include fixed wireless services when assessing the current state
of competition in mobile markets, we recognise that there are likely to be some
economies of scope on the supply side which may affect decisions around entry
and expansion by MNOs and MVNOs.
2.23 The ability to offer fixed wireless services will depend on spectrum holdings, in
particularly the frequency bands required to deliver the capacity associated with
fixed wireless services. We also note that fixed wireless services are likely to be an
important feature of 5G deployments and possible MVNO product offerings.
2.24 Mobile services have typically been offered to consumers through two types of
retail plans. Prepay plans are where consumers pay for services in advance, and on-
account plans, also called post-pay, are where consumers pay at the end of each
month of service.
2.25 On-account plans may be in the following forms:
fixed-term contracts, where the consumer signs up for a contract period
of, for example, 12 or 24 months. In the past, these plans have typically
been offered with a handset discount, and with the consumer facing an
early termination charge to break the contract; and
open term plans, where the consumer pays for the service on a month by
month basis and is not locked into a fixed-term contract.
2.26 Mobile service providers in New Zealand have moved more towards offering open
term plans for residential customers. These can be paired with monthly interest
free payments for new handsets. Interest free payments spread the purchase price
of a handset across a 12, 24 or 36-month period with the option to pay off the
remaining amount in full at any point.
2.27 If the customer switches to another supplier, they are required to pay the balance
on the handset and in some cases to repay any discount the customer received at
the time of purchasing the handset. Spark’s, Vodafone’s and 2degrees current
10
In its Annual Report 2019, Chorus also referred to competition from wireless networks contributing to a
reduction in its copper-based broadband revenues (from ADSL and VDSL services). Chorus, Annual Report
2019, p 21.
11
We note that the boundary between fixed services (fixed-line and fixed wireless) and mobile services may
become increasingly blurred, eg as a result of WiFi.
25
handset promotional offers all appear to relate to open term plans with interest
free payments.
12
2.28 Both types of on-account plans lock consumers who pair their purchase of handsets
into a payment period. However, by separating the cost of the handset from the
cost of the mobile service, the open term plans make the handset portion of the
cost more transparent, potentially allowing consumers more flexibility and choice
when considering switching plans or providers.
2.29 The on-account market can be further split into residential and business segments.
2.30 Mobile plans are typically made up of a set ‘bundle’ of texts, calls, and data. The
majority of plans have data caps; however, there have been moves recently
towards plans that are marketed as having uncapped or unlimited data. These
uncapped data plans are not truly unlimited as they are subject to fair-use terms
and MNOs severely throttle customers’ speeds after a certain amount of data has
been consumed. We are currently considering whether the use of the term
unlimited in describing these plans has the potential to mislead consumers and
breach the Fair Trading Act 1986.
2.31 A number of the unlimited’ plans currently available include a group or shared
option, where the price per user reduces if additional users are added.
Mobile service providers
2.32 There are two types of service providers competing in the supply of mobile services
to consumers.
MNOs own key mobile network infrastructure (such as spectrum, cell
towers, radio access and core network equipment) and supply mobile
services to wholesale and retail customers. The ability to offer coverage is
important due to the mobility of demand. An MNO can offer coverage by
building its own national network or by sharing capacity (either through
co-location or roaming). MNOs may launch sub-brands to target specific
segments of the retail market.
MVNOs are operators that provide mobile services to consumers but
generally do not own licenced radio spectrum or much of the
infrastructure required to provide mobile services. Instead, MVNOs rely on
buying wholesale services from an MNO. The amount of control an MVNO
12
As advertised online as of September 2019.
26
has over the services it offers will vary according to the nature of its
agreement with its host MNO.
2.33 There are different types of MVNO operating models. These are typically described
as ranging from a licensed reseller, which is the minimalist form of MVNO, through
various intermediate models, to a ‘full’ MVNO (sometimes also referred to as a
‘thick’ MVNO). Under a full MVNO model, the MVNO invests in more of the key
components of a mobile network. The MVNO models offer the MNO the
opportunity to generate revenue from spare network capacity and to reach
customer segments where the MVNO may have better reach.
Mobile regulatory settings in New Zealand
2.34 There are two types of regulated telecommunications services in Schedule 1 of the
Telecommunications Act:
specified services, for which we Commission can determine non-price
terms; and
designated services, where the Commission can determine price terms and
non-price terms.
2.35 We set the terms of access for the regulated services through a Standard Terms
Determination (STD).
2.36 Table 1 outlines the mobile services currently included in Schedule 1 of the
Telecommunications Act.
Table 1 Specified and designated mobile services in Schedule 1
13
Service
Type
Introduced
Next Schedule 3
review due
Subject to
an STD
Mobile termination
access service (MTAS)
Designated
23 September 2010
23 September 2020
Yes
Mobile co-location
Specified
19 December 2001
30 June 2021
Yes
14
Local and mobile
number portability
Designated
19 December 2001
30 June 2021
Yes
National roaming
Specified
19 December 2001
20 September 2023
No
13
These services, and the reasons why they are listed in Schedule 1 of the Telecommunications Act 2001, are
discussed further in Chapter 7.
14
The STD for mobile co-location was first introduced in 2008.
27
2.37 Mobile termination access services (MTAS) are the termination services a network
operator needs to purchase to allow its subscribers to communicate with the
subscribers of another mobile network.
15
2.38 Mobile co-location is a service that enables an MNO to install mobile network
transmission and reception equipment on the mast of another MNO.
16
2.39 Local and mobile number portability allows customers to keep their number when
switching between service providers.
17
2.40 National roaming allows customers of one mobile network to use another network
when they are outside their own service provider’s coverage area.
18
2.41 In November 2018 a new Part 7 was also added to the Telecommunications Act,
which provides for the introduction of retail service quality obligations and powers,
including the ability for the Commission to review existing industry codes and
create codes of conduct that could apply to mobile services.
Changes to regulation
2.42 Schedule 3 of the Telecommunications Act sets out the process for altering
regulated services in Schedule 1 of the Telecommunications Act.
Under clause 1(1) of Schedule 3, we can investigate whether to add a new
service to Schedule 1, amend an existing service in Schedule 1, or remove
a service from Schedule 1, if we are satisfied that there are reasonable
grounds for an investigation into the matter.
Under clause 1(3) of Schedule 3, we must consider, at no more than 5
yearly intervals from when a Schedule 1 service came into force, whether
there are reasonable grounds for commencing an investigation into
whether that service should be deregulated (by removing it from
Schedule 1).
15
Commerce Commission, “Review of MTAS as a designated service”, (23 September 2015).
16
Commerce Commission, “Review of Designated and Specified Services under Schedule 1 of the
Telecommunications Act 2001”, [2016] NZCC 13, (5 July 2016).
17
Commerce Commission, “Review of Designated and Specified Services under Schedule 1 of the
Telecommunications Act 2001”, [2016] NZCC 13, (5 July 2016).
18
Commerce Commission, “Final decision on consideration of deregulation of national roaming”, [2018]
NZCC 14, 4 September 2018.
28
Chapter 3 Development of mobile services and
competition
Purpose and structure of this chapter
Purpose
3.1 This chapter looks at the development of competition in the supply of mobile
services in New Zealand. We focus on how competition has evolved, and whether
there are any factors which may have affected market dynamics in recent years.
Structure
3.2 This chapter sets out:
our analysis of how the mobile market has performed in delivering
outcomes to mobile consumers. This includes our examination of a
number of key indicators: market structure and market shares, bundling of
services, pricing, usage trends, investment, profitability, quality of mobile
services, and consumer satisfaction; and
the identification of a number of key issues which are in our view likely to
underpin the further development of competition in the mobile market
going forward. These are discussed in more detail in Chapter 4.
Analysis of the mobile market
3.3 During this study, we have examined how the retail market for mobile services has
performed in New Zealand. We have taken into account the following:
information that we have previously summarised in our Issues Paper and
our Preliminary Findings Paper;
submissions received on the Issues Paper, and submissions and cross-
submissions on the Preliminary Findings Paper;
industry responses to our 2018 annual monitoring questionnaire; and
updated price benchmarking results from Teligen.
29
3.4 There have also been other developments since we released our Issues Paper that
are relevant to the mobile services market in New Zealand. These include:
Dense Air’s acquisition of spectrum and its plans to use small-cell
technology to complement existing mobile coverage;
Infratil’s acquisition of a 50% share in Vodafone New Zealand;
19
Trustpower’s announcement that they had signed an MVNO agreement
with Spark; and
Kogan’s announcement that they had signed an MVNO agreement with
Vodafone. Kogan launched mobile services in New Zealand in September
2019.
3.5 In considering competitive conditions in the retail mobile market, we have
examined a range of key competition indicators, which we discuss in the following
sections. These indicators are relevant to how the retail mobile market has
performed in terms of delivering outcomes to mobile consumers in New Zealand.
Spark supported the use of a range of competition indicators in any market
analysis, particularly given the rapid change observed in mobile markets.
20
Market structure and market shares
3.6 Retail mobile services are predominantly supplied by the three MNOs, Spark,
21
Vodafone,
22
and 2degrees.
23
In addition, several access-based MVNOs, Warehouse
Mobile, Vocus, and Compass, serve a small share of mobile subscribers. Kogan
Mobile has also recently started offering prepaid mobile services.
3.7 Table 2 summarises the number of mobile subscribers in New Zealand as of
June 2018, based on responses to our 2018 annual monitoring questionnaire.
19
On 12 July 2019, Infratil announced that it and Brookfield Asset Management had received regulatory
approvals from the Commerce Commission and the Overseas Investment Office to acquire Vodafone
New Zealand.
20
Spark, “Mobile market Study Preliminary Findings: Submission” (28 June 2019), para 11.
21
Spark New Zealand is a publicly traded company.
22
As noted above, Vodafone New Zealand was acquired by Infratil and Brookfield Asset Management. The
transaction completed on 31 July 2019. Infratil, “Completion of acquisition of Vodafone New Zealand”,
(31 June 2019).
23
2degrees’ parent company is Trilogy International Partners.
30
Table 2 Mobile subscribers, 2018
Provider
Subscribers
%
Vodafone
2,591,092
40.5%
Spark (including Skinny)
2,423,532
37.9%
2degrees
1,313,497
20.5%
Total MNOs
6,328,121
98.9%
MVNOs (Warehouse Mobile, Vocus, Compass)
69,261
1.1%
Total
6,397,382
100.0%
Source: Responses to 2018 annual monitoring questionnaire
3.8 A number of parties have announced that they have secured wholesale agreements
with MNOs, which have allowed them to, or will allow them to enter the mobile
market in New Zealand as MVNOs.
Kogan Mobile has signed a commercial MVNO agreement with
Vodafone.
24
Kogan launched mobile services in New Zealand in
September 2019.
25
In November 2018, Trustpower announced that it had secured an MVNO
agreement with Spark. This will enable Trustpower to start offering mobile
and wireless broadband services.
26
Trustpower, which also supplies retail
electricity, said it had nearly 400,000 customers in total, including 96,000
fixed-line telecommunications customers.
27
3.9 Nova has recently entered the mobile market through its acquisition of an existing
MVNO, MegaTEL.
28
24
Corinne Reichert, “Kogan Mobile launches off Vodafone in New Zealand.” ZDNet, (4 June 2018).
https://www.zdnet.com/article/kogan-mobile-launches-off-vodafone-in-new-zealand/.
25
https://www.zdnet.com/article/kogan-mobile-live-in-new-zealand-as-prepay-player.
26
Trustpower media release, “Trustpower pleased to announce wireless broadband and mobile services on
the way for customers”, 20 November 2018.
27
Trustpower Annual Report 2019, p 38.
28
Nova submission on the Preliminary Findings Paper, (28 June 2019), para 3.
31
3.10 MyRepublic has also announced that it intends to launch MVNO services in
New Zealand.
29
3.11 Vocus currently has an MVNO agreement with Spark, and it has announced that it
intends to test the wholesale market by issuing a request for proposal for its MVNO
business.
30
3.12 In addition, towards the end of 2018, Dense Air acquired 70 MHz of spectrum in the
2.5 GHz band from Blue Reach and Cayman Wireless.
31
Dense Air has informed us
that it intends to use the spectrum to offer network extension services to the
existing MNOs in New Zealand (similar to what it does in other countries), by using
small-cell technology at the edge of cells to enhance coverage. Dense Air’s entry is
more complementary to the existing MNOs, as Dense Air does not intend to
compete with existing mobile operators at either the retail or wholesale level.
3.13 Figure 3 shows trends in mobile market shares, including 2018 data from our latest
annual monitoring questionnaire. As shown in Figure 3, over the last 10 years:
2degrees initially rapidly increased its share of total mobile subscribers,
reaching 22% by 2013. Since 2013, 2degrees share of subscribers has
remained flat, with a small fall reported in 2018, to 21% (from 24% in
2017). As we noted in the 2018 Annual Monitoring Report, this was largely
a result of the closure of its 2G network in early 2018;
32
Vodafone’s share of mobile subscribers has fallen steadily from around
53% in 2009 to 41% in 2018; and
Spark’s share of subscribers dropped from 46% in 2009 to 34% by 2013,
recovering in recent years as Spark’s Skinny brand, launched in early 2012,
expanded.
29
Communications Day, “MyRepublic plans ANZ MVNO launch within a year”, (26 June 2018), and
Commerce Commission correspondence with MyRepublic.
30
Vocus submission on the Preliminary Findings Paper, (28 June 2019), para 17.
31
See http://denseair.net/dense-air-acquires-2-6-ghz-spectrum-assets-in-new-zealand/.
32
Commerce Commission, “Annual Telecommunications Monitoring Report 2018 Key Facts”, (18 December
2018), p 19.
32
Figure 3 Mobile market shares total subscribers
3.14 Competition in the supply of mobile services has strengthened since the arrival of
2degrees in 2009. The retail market has become less concentrated as 2degrees has
gained market share, particularly in the prepaid mobile services market segment
but also more recently in the on-account residential mobile services market
segment. TUANZ submitted that the continuing presence and expansion of
2degrees in the mobile market is critical.
33
We agree that the emergence of
2degrees has been important in the development of an increasingly competitive
mobile market.
3.15 The prepaid mobile services segment is relatively low value; based on responses to
our annual monitoring questionnaire, the average revenue per user (ARPU) for
prepaid customers was $12 per month in 2018, compared to ARPU for on-account
subscribers of $43 per month.
3.16 The business segment has remained more concentrated, and this led us to
undertake a study in 2015 to see whether there were any barriers to expansion in
this segment.
34
The 2015 study identified a number of key factors that business
customers value when selecting a mobile provider. These include reliable coverage,
good customer service, competitive pricing, the ability to offer bundles of services,
and having an established reputation.
33
TUANZ submission on the Preliminary Findings Paper, (30 June 2019), para 14.
34
Commerce Commission, “Summary of business mobile market segment study” (30 March 2017)
https://comcom.govt.nz/regulated-industries/telecommunications/monitoring-the-telecommunications-
market/topic-papers-other-reports-and-studies/business-mobile-market-study.
33
3.17 The 2015 study also found a perception among business customers that 2degrees
represented a lower cost, low quality brand with less coverage, although 2degrees’
own business customers reported the highest levels of satisfaction.
3.18 In revenue terms, 2degrees’ retail market share remained unchanged in 2018,
while Spark’s share increased slightly, and Vodafone’s share continued to drop.
2degrees on-account residential mobile revenues have been increasingly
important, and this trend continued during 2018.
3.19 One factor influencing changes in market share is the level of porting activity.
Approximately five percent of New Zealand mobile subscribers port their number
each year. In the year ending June 2018, a total of 301,762 mobile numbers were
ported.
3.20 A number of submissions have argued that the mobile market remains highly
concentrated, with a high proportion of customers served by only 3 MNOs.
According to these submitters, there is little competitive threat from MVNOs,
whose collective market share is low in New Zealand.
35
3.21 As shown in Table 2 above, the share of mobile subscribers supplied by MVNOs in
New Zealand is around 1%. However, MVNO market share is only one indicator of
competition in a market. As noted earlier in paragraph 3.5, we have examined a
range of indicators, including market shares more generally, as well as the
indicators discussed below.
3.22 As discussed later in this report, we also consider that competitive conditions at the
wholesale level have been improving in recent years, and that this is likely to be in
large part due to 2degrees becoming more active in pursuing wholesale
opportunities. This increased competition at the wholesale level has led to
improvements in the commercial terms offered to MVNOs and potential MVNOs,
allowing for new MVNO-based entry to emerge. This should lead to an expansion in
the MVNO share where MVNOs are able to offer value to consumers.
35
Vocus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 2; BAINZ Consulting, submission on
the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 2; Nova, submission on the Preliminary Findings paper,
(28 June 2019), para 7; Internet NZ submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 17.
34
Bundling
3.23 Bundling of multiple services can be beneficial for consumers by offering
convenience of single billing or by offering cheaper prices when the services are
purchased in a bundle than when purchased separately. However, potential
competition concerns may arise if a service provider offers bundles of services that
its competitors cannot replicate.
3.24 In the case of bundles involving mobile services, such foreclosure concerns may be
mitigated by competition between the MNOs, unless an MNO offers a “must have”
service that the others cannot replicate. In addition, bundling can increase
consumer stickiness and customer acquisition costs which could potentially soften
competition.
3.25 Chorus, Vocus and Trustpower submitted that the ability of non-MNOs to compete
in retail markets may be constrained unless they are able to obtain wholesale
access to mobile services on reasonable terms.
36
For example, according to
Trustpower, the bundling of fixed-line and mobile services are continuing to grow,
with a particular appeal to high-value customer segments. Trustpower noted that
wholesale access to mobile services will be important for fixed-line only providers
in order to avoid the MNOs foreclosing more valuable customer segments.
37
Analysys Mason made a similar point:
38
The anticipated increase in popularity of bundles in New Zealand’s telecoms market,
as well as the shift from prepaid to contract subscriptions, suggests that customers
will increasingly choose to purchase domestic telecoms (and family member)
bundles inclusive of mobile services. The convenience and savings offered by
fixedmobile bundling means that operators which lack a mobile product will find it
much harder to attract high-value customer groups, regardless of the other
telecoms, TV or utility products offered in the bundle.
3.26 Trustpower submitted that this differs materially from bundling fixed-line and
electricity services, as the inputs required to supply these services are easily
accessible due to there being open wholesale markets with regulated access for
these services.
39
3.27 Consumers have benefitted from discounts by bundling fixed and mobile services.
For example, in the past, the three MNOs have all offered discounted prices for
36
Chorus submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), para 16; Vocus submission on the Issues paper,
(26 October 2018), para 89-94; Trustpower submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 15.
37
Trustpower submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), para 3.5.2; Trustpower submission on the
Preliminary Findings Paper (28 June 2019), p 8.
38
Analysys Mason, “Final Report for Trustpower: MVNO aspects of the Commission’s mobile market review”
(28 October 2018), p 23.
39
Trustpower submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), para 3.5.3.
35
residential fixed broadband services if a qualifying mobile subscription is also
purchased.
3.28 According to the responses to our 2018 annual monitoring questionnaire the
volume of fixed broadband subscriptions that attracted such a discount accounted
for less than 20% of the fixed broadband services supplied by the MNOs, although
it has been increasing.
3.29 The 2018 Consumer NZ survey results indicate that 73% of respondents do not
purchase a product that bundles their mobile service with other services.
40
,
41
Of
those who do purchase mobile services as part of a bundle, the main services
included with mobile are fixed-line broadband services and content.
3.30 The ability to bundle mobile connectivity with content was ranked relatively low by
respondents to Analysys Mason’s Connected Consumer Survey in New Zealand.
According to the 2018 survey results, the most important factors that influence
mobile consumers’ choice of a mobile plan include lower pricing of mobile services
(52%), data allowances (33%), value (24%), network coverage (16%), and data
speeds (15%).
42
Bundling mobile with music was an influential factor for 8% of
respondents and bundling with video content was influential for 2%.
3.31 Spark has moved away from offering discounts to customers who purchase both
fixed and mobile services from Spark. For example, Spark noted that its new
‘Unplan’ broadband plan does not offer a bundled discount, and that it expects the
number of bundled discounts involving mobile to fall over time as customers
migrate to its new broadband plans. According to Spark,
43
It is unclear whether bundling of mobile services may be a concern in the future. But
bundling can only be a concern where the bundle includes an element with market
power and there isn’t effective competition for the bundle, i.e. a fixed/mobile
bundle may compete against a fixed/electricity bundle. If anything, communications
markets are expected to be more competitive over time, leading us to conclude that
bundling of mobile services is unlikely at this time to represent a potential
competition problem.
40
Consumer NZ, Telco Consumer Survey 2018. Survey conducted in December 2018, select results published
February 2019.
41
We note that the actual proportion of respondents who do not purchase a bundle of mobile and other
services may be higher than 73%. Some Skinny respondents said they bought a mobile bundle with
broadband. However, Skinny does not offer bundles of mobile and broadband services. The respondents
may be buying both mobile and broadband services from Skinny, but it is not a ‘bundle’ in that the
services are not tied or billed together.
42
Analysys Mason, “Connected Consumer Survey 2018: mobile customer satisfaction in Australia and
New Zealand”, slide 11.
43
Spark submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), para 46.
36
3.32 Although Spark has moved away from such bundling, the other MNOs are
continuing to offer bundled discounts across fixed and mobile services, and as
noted above, the aggregate number of discounted services has been gradually
increasing.
3.33 At this stage, it appears that non-MNOs, such as Vocus, Trustpower, and Nova (who
has recently acquired an MVNO, MegaTEL) have been able to offer, or expect to
offer, similar or new bundles, for example involving fixed and mobile services along
with other services such as electricity.
Vocus offers discounts to residential customers who purchase both fixed-
line broadband and mobile from Vocus.
44
In announcing its intention to offer mobile services, Trustpower said that
mobile is increasingly important to its customers, and that its wholesale
agreement with Spark will enable it to offer a wider range of bundles to its
customers.
45
Pricing
3.34 Mobile consumers typically purchase bundles of mobile services which provide a
monthly allowance of minutes, texts, and data.
3.35 Throughout this study, we have had regard to the benchmarking of mobile prices
undertaken by Teligen on behalf of the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD), which we use in our annual monitoring reports.
46
In order to
examine how prices for mobile services have moved over time and how prices in
New Zealand compare to other countries, Teligen’s benchmarking considers the
cost of filling various usage baskets. Teligen’s price benchmarking of mobile
services is based on the two largest MNOs in each country in the OECD and allows
prices to be compared across a range of usage baskets. Teligen updates its
benchmarking three to four times each year.
44
Slingshot website accessed September 2019. The discount offered by Slingshot amounts to a $300 credit
over 12 months.
45
Trustpower media release, “Trustpower pleased to announce wireless broadband and mobile services on
the way for customers”, (20 November 2018).
46
See for example, Commerce Commission, “Annual Telecommunications Monitoring report: 2018 Key
facts”, (18 December 2018), Table 3.
37
3.36 A number of submissions have commented on the pricing of mobile services in
New Zealand.
2degrees: New Zealand has a small population and challenging
topography, making it relatively expensive to supply mobile services.
Despite this, since 2degrees entry, New Zealand’s ranking in terms of
mobile pricing has improved compared to other OECD countries.
47
2degrees: Benchmarking can overlook important differences. For example,
many Australian mobile plans are for fixed-term contracts; in New Zealand,
2degrees introduced open term plans and monthly repayment options for
handsets.
48
Spark: Referred to open term plans in New Zealand versus fixed-term
contracts in Australia, and that some of the Australian high usage plans
referred to in the Issues Paper included promotional bonus data
allowances and minimum 12-month contract terms.
49
Spark: Recent competitive developments in New Zealand have led to
further improvements in value for money for high usage plans. Spark has
increased the threshold on its ‘unlimited’ plans from 22GB to 40GB. Spark
noted that other operators offer group plans with up to 40GB per person
for as low as $40 per month. Such plans compare favourably to other
countries, including Australia.
50
NERA: The OECD’s August 2018 benchmarking shows New Zealand prices
below both the OECD average and Australia for low and high usage baskets
(including unlimited calls + 20GB, and unlimited calls + unlimited data).
NERA also said that it was important to consider price trends over time,
that prices per GB have been declining steeply in New Zealand, and that
the emergence of high usage plans (20GB and unlimited data) and price
reductions for these plans in recent years is consistent with competition
occurring as demand develops.
51
Vodafone: New mobile plans introduced by the New Zealand MNOs in
2017 with high or unlimited data allowances have brought New Zealand
much more in line with other OECD countries. For example, Vodafone
47
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (October 2018), p 12.
48
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (October 2018), p 12, 28.
49
Spark submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), para 27.
50
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 9c.
51
NERA, “Competition in the New Zealand Mobile Market”, (26 October 2018), para 38-40.
38
submitted that New Zealand’s ‘unlimited plans compare well to
comparable offers in Australia.
52
Data caps continue to increase in
New Zealand, with Vodafone increasing the cap on its Red+ plans to 40GB,
and 2degrees increasing the speed threshold on its unlimited plans to
40GB.
53
Vocus: In the absence of disruptive offers from MVNOs, MNOs have little
incentive to compete down high prices of larger data plans, despite
increasing demand for data.
54
BAINZ Consulting: There is little price differentiation in New Zealand, and
the pricing for mobile services in New Zealand are higher than Australia.
55
Sky: Although prices for low and medium usage bundles in New Zealand
seem to compare well with other OECD countries, New Zealand consumers
pay more for high usage bundles than in other countries, particularly
Australia. It is difficult to reconcile this with the finding that conditions for
effective competition exist.
56
Chorus: It is not clear why higher volume mobile bundles are expensive in
New Zealand compared to other countries. In New Zealand, there are
significant price differences between mobile broadband and fixed wireless
services, suggesting cross-subsidisation and insufficient competition for
mobile.
57
3.37 Mobile plans offering higher volumes of data are becoming increasingly popular
and important. As an example, the total number of residential on-account
subscribers purchasing bundles of voice, SMS, and data allowances of 3GB or more
increased from 133,000 subscribers in 2016, to 319,000 subscribers in 2017. This
has continued to increase, to 497,000 subscribers in 2018. According to Spark, the
predominant trend in the retail market is the shift towards unlimited data plans,
including plans that can be shared across several users.
58
3.38 To reflect the increasing importance of high usage plans, our 2018 Annual
Monitoring Report included a number of higher usage baskets (including unlimited
52
Vodafone submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 29.
53
Vodafone submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 4.
54
Vocus submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), para 96.
55
BAINZ Consulting submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 1.
56
Sky submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 10.1, 14.
57
Chorus submission on the Issues Paper, (26 October 2018), page 7; Chorus submission on the Preliminary
Findings paper (28 June 2019), p 3.
58
Spark cross-submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (19 July 2019), para 10.
39
calls and 20GB) when comparing mobile prices in New Zealand and other countries.
During this study, we have had regard to a range of baskets, including the unlimited
calls and 20GB data basket, when comparing mobile pricing.
3.39 NERA’s submission on the Issues Paper claimed that the OECD’s August 2018
benchmarking shows that New Zealand performs better than both the OECD
average and Australia, including for high usage baskets. However, we note that in
Teligen’s initial results for its August 2018 benchmarking, which were discussed by
NERA in its submission, Teligen had incorrectly reported a price for New Zealand
based on a Skinny plan with a data allowance that did not fill the 20GB basket.
59
60
When corrected, New Zealand’s price for that basket remained 23% higher than
Australia, but below the OECD average.
3.40 We note that Teligen no longer considers New Zealand’s ‘unlimited data’ plans
(where speed is throttled once a threshold has been reached) to qualify as
unlimited data plans, and so New Zealand no longer appears in the Teligen results
for that basket.
3.41 Table 3 shows the May 2019 results for the same baskets that we used in the 2018
Annual Monitoring Report. For comparison, the figures in brackets are the August
2018 results reported in our 2018 Annual Monitoring Report.
Table 3 Latest Teligen benchmarking results, May 2019
May 2019 price, NZD PPP
(Aug 2018)
NZ % price variance from
Mobile phone
services basket
NZ rank
in OECD*
NZ
Aust.
OECD
average
Aust.
OECD
average
30 calls + 500MB
10/37
(8/36)
17
(16)
13
(22)
24
(26)
29%
-32%
100 calls + 2GB
17/37
(15/36)
28
(28)
13
(22)
35
(41)
115%
-22%
300 calls + 5GB
21/37
(17/36)
48
(45)
13
(34)
48
(56)
270%
-1%
unlimited calls +
20GB
20/33
(16/31)
72
(65)
26
(53)
86
(109)
178%
-17%
* A ranking of 1 indicates the lowest price for that basket in the OECD.
Source: based on Teligen benchmarking results, May 2019.
59
NERA, “Competition in the NZ mobile market) submission on the Issues Paper”, (26 October 2018), p 14.
60
The plan was Skinny’s $46 Combo, which has 12GB data.
40
3.42 As discussed further in the following section, the average volume of data used by
mobile consumers in New Zealand was 2GB per month in 2018, although this is
growing strongly. For the 2GB and 5GB baskets, the New Zealand price reported by
Teligen is currently at or below the OECD average, as illustrated in Figure 4 and
Figure 5.
Figure 4 Mobile prices (100 calls + 2GB)
Figure 5 Mobile prices (300 calls + 5GB)
3.43 For the larger usage baskets, the results shown in Table 3 indicate that mobile
prices in New Zealand are relatively high when compared to Australia but remain
below the average for the OECD. In fact, New Zealand’s ranking has slightly
deteriorated since the August 2018 results (used in our 2018 Annual Monitoring
Report). For example, in the unlimited calls + 20GB basket, the August 2018 results
reported New Zealand as 16th most expensive out of 31 countries; in the February
and May 2019 results, New Zealand’s rank had fallen to 20
th
out of 33 countries.
41
3.44 The reason for this appears to be the withdrawal by Skinny of its sub-brand (‘Skinny
Direct’) in respect of new customers towards the end of 2018. Skinny Direct’s retail
plans were the cheapest plans in New Zealand for some of the higher usage baskets
used by Teligen. For example, for the unlimited calls + 20GB basket, the cheapest
plan in New Zealand had been Skinny Direct’s 25GB plan (NZ$65 per month), which
appeared in Teligen’s benchmarking results in May and August 2018.
3.45 In Teligen’s May 2019 benchmarking, Skinny Direct’s plans no longer appear, with
the cheapest plan in New Zealand now Skinny’s NZ$66 plan (per 4 weeks), which is
equivalent to NZ$71.50 per month. While below the OECD average for this basket
(NZ$86), this remains significantly higher than the price in Australia (NZ$26), as
shown in Table 3.
3.46 Although the New Zealand prices for the higher usage baskets shown in Table 3 are
relatively high compared to Australia, it should be noted that the New Zealand
plans reported by Teligen provide more data than is required to fill the Teligen
baskets. For example, in the unlimited calls + 20GB basket, Skinny’s plan provides
for 33GB of data each month (the Australian plan reported by Teligen for this
basket provides for 20GB of data).
3.47 We have also compared specific retail mobile plans available in New Zealand and
Australia. The New Zealand MNOs do not offer fixed-term contracts to residential
customers, with retail plans available on a pay-monthly basis. In Australia, Optus
and Vodafone currently offer both pay-monthly mobile plans as well as 12-month
contract plans, with greater value offered under the latter. Telstra has recently
moved away from mobile plans with fixed-term contracts, and now offers plans on
a pay-monthly basis only.
61
3.48 Table 4 summarises the highest data plans currently offered by each MNO in
Australia and New Zealand.
62
61
Telstra media release, “Telstra says goodbye to lock-in plans and introduces new build-your-own mobile
plans”, (25 June 2019).
62
Prices of the Australian plans are converted to NZ$ using PPP rates derived from the Teligen benchmarking
(May 2019).
42
Table 4 Mobile prices (price per GB), highest data plans offered
Pay-monthly
Vodafone
Australia
Telstra
2degrees
Skinny
Spark
Vodafone
Price (NZ$)
$56
$103
$85
$83
$80
$80
Data (GB)
15
150
40
43
40
40
Price per GB
$3.76
$0.68
$2.13
$1.93
$2.00
$2.00
National calls
and SMS
unlimited
unlimited
unlimited
(incl to Aus)
unlimited
(incl to Aus)
unlimited
(incl to Aus)
unlimited
(incl to Aus)
12-month
contract
Optus
Vodafone
Australia
Price (NZ$)
$81
$67
Data (GB)
120
120
Price per GB
$0.68
$0.56
Source: operator websites, accessed September 2019. Prices are for the highest data plans offered by each
MNO in Australia and New Zealand
3.49 In the Preliminary Findings paper, we noted that for pay-monthly plans, the value
offered by the New Zealand MNOs was similar to the plans available in Australia,
although considerably higher value was available in Australia for customers who
are prepared to sign up for a 12-month term. While it remains the case that the
price per GB remains higher in New Zealand for the largest bundles, there have
been a number of recent market developments which have resulted in improved
value for higher usage mobile consumers in New Zealand.
In April 2019, 2degrees introduced a shared ‘unlimited’ mobile plan,
offering 40GB for $85 per month. The average price per subscriber drops
as additional subscribers are added. A maximum of four people are able to
subscribe to the plan, at which point the average price per subscriber is
$40 per month for 40GB. In addition, 2degrees offered a short-term
promotion in June 2019, offering a 50% discount on most of its
pay-monthly prices for three months.
In May 2019, Skinny added a 40GB plan for $77, renewing every four
weeks. When adjusted to a monthly basis, the Skinny plan offers 43GB for
$83.
43
As Spark noted in its submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, it
recently increased the threshold at which speeds are throttled on its
unlimited mobile plans, from 22GB to 40GB.
63
According to Spark, there
has been a significant shift towards such plans in the New Zealand
market.
64
Vodafone has also recently increased the threshold on its unlimited
plans, from 22GB to 40GB.
in September 2019, Kogan Mobile commenced offering prepaid mobile
plans with unlimited calls and SMS, and up to 32GB per month. Subscribers
can pay in advance for 30 days, 90 days, or 365 days.
3.50 We also note that the various plans shown in Table 4 have different inclusions. For
example, some of the New Zealand plans include subscriptions to content (such as
Netflix and Spotify), while the Australian plans often include services such as
picture messaging, international calls, and in some cases international roaming.
3.51 Spark submitted that New Zealand MNOs have moved away from fixed-term
contract plans following feedback from consumers and the Commission.
65
Our
concerns with contracts were with the one-sided nature of the conditions and
unfair penalties for termination that existed in contracts at the time. Unfair
contract terms can apply to any kind of contract, whether fixed or open term.
3.52 The use of fixed-term contracts per se is not necessarily problematic. As noted
above, consumers in Australia have the choice of fixed-term contracts and
pay-monthly plans. Consumers who are prepared to sign up for a 12-month term
can receive higher value compared to the pay-monthly plans.
3.53 In the Consumer NZ survey, respondents were asked what is the one thing that
their mobile service provider could do to increase overall satisfaction. Having an
‘open term’ plan was the least important feature, with better pricing, cheaper data,
and better service quality being the most important.
66
This suggests that
consumers might be willing to enter fixed-term contracts in order to get better
value, although as noted above, the pay-monthly plans available in New Zealand
63
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 9c.
64
Spark cross-submission on Preliminary Findings paper, (19 July 2019), para 10.
65
Spark submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), para 27b. Spark has since clarified to the
Commission that they were referring to our comments on the management of fixed term contracts,
particularly the actions we have taken against parties who included what we considered may be
potentially unfair contract terms within a fixed term contract structure.
66
Consumer NZ, Telco Consumer Survey 2018.
44
continue to offer improved value to consumers through higher data thresholds as
well as lower prices for shared plans.
3.54 A number of submissions earlier in our study (on the Issues Paper) responded to
Analysys Mason’s observation that mobile ARPU has been increasing in
New Zealand in recent years. NERA claimed that the Analysys Mason result appears
to have been driven by an anomaly in the Global System for Mobile Communication
Association (GSMA) data reported for Vodafone.
67
3.55 Vodafone submitted that the GSMA data includes fixed and mobile revenues, which
spiked in 2013 as a result of Vodafone’s acquisition of TelstraClear (which included
high-value fixed-line enterprise customers). Vodafone also submitted that the
GSMA data for 2016 contained an error. Vodafone referred to the revenue and
subscriber data supplied to us as part of the annual monitoring questionnaire,
which shows ARPU declining since 2010.
68
3.56 Figure 6 summarises the estimated mobile ARPU based on the responses to our
annual monitoring questionnaires. This indicates that mobile ARPU in New Zealand
has been flat (or shows a slight decline if handset revenues are excluded, as shown
by the dotted line).
3.57 The increase in ARPU in 2012/13 appears to have been driven by an increase in
Spark’s ARPU, which in turn was related to the closure of its CDMA network. As we
have previously noted, the closure of the CDMA network in 2012 resulted in a
reduction in the number of Spark’s subscribers.
69
Spark reported that the loss of
lower value prepaid subscribers resulted in an increase in its mobile ARPU in
2013.
70
67
NERA, “Competition in the New Zealand Mobile Market”, (26 October 2018), para 54.
68
Vodafone submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 6-7.
69
Commerce Commission, “Annual Telecommunications Monitoring Report 2013”, (21 May 2014), p 23-24.
70
Spark Annual Report 2013, p 53.
45
Figure 6 Mobile ARPU, 2008-2018
3.58 As noted in the following section, the average monthly volume of mobile-originated
calling minutes per mobile subscriber has been increasing over this period, as has
the average volume of mobile data per mobile subscriber.
3.59 These ARPU and usage trends are consistent with falling prices for mobile services
over time.
3.60 A further indication of how prices of mobile services have changed over time can
be seen by comparing Teligen’s benchmarking results for a consistent basket. For
example, Teligen has reported benchmarking results for a basket of 900 calls and
2GB since 2012.
In 2012, the cheapest mobile plan in New Zealand which filled this basket
was a Telecom plan offering calls and 2GB for $139 per month.
In 2019, the cheapest mobile plan is a Skinny plan offering calls and 5GB
for $39 per month.
71
3.61 Chorus has submitted that there appear to be significant differences in prices per
GB between mobile broadband and fixed wireless services. Chorus submitted that
this may reflect insufficient competition for mobile services, which may be cross-
71
The Skinny plan is Skinny’s $36 Combo, which renews every four weeks. This price is adjusted by Teligen to
be equivalent to a price per month. The monthly equivalent data allowance would be 5.4 GB per month.
46
subsidising fixed wireless services.
72
However, we note that fixed wireless services
are location-specific, providing connectivity to consumers at fixed locations.
3.62 As a result, the capacity required to support such services can more easily be
directed to those fixed locations. In contrast, for mobile broadband services,
demand is mobile as consumers are likely to be moving around, including between
cell sites. This mobility of demand makes mobile services more challenging to
deliver in terms of network management.
Usage trends
3.63 Responses to our 2018 annual monitoring questionnaire show that mobile voice
minutes continued to grow during 2018, both in aggregate and on a per subscriber
basis. SMS volumes continued to decline as consumers increasingly favour OTT-
based messaging services. This is particularly evident from Analysys Mason’s
Connected Consumer Survey 2018, which found the following:
73
81% of smartphone users in New Zealand use OTT communication and
social media services, with penetration particularly high in younger cohorts
(94%-95% among users aged below 34); and
messaging services were the most common OTT service used by
respondents.
3.64 In our 2018 Annual Monitoring Report, we noted that the volume of data used by
mobile consumers continued to grow strongly in 2018, with the average volume of
mobile data per connection reaching 2GB per month in 2018, up from 1.2 GB in
2017, as shown in Figure 7. The OECD has reported that average data usage in
New Zealand has increased by 130% between 2016 and 2018.
74
72
Chorus submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 7; Chorus submission on the Preliminary
Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 5.5.
73
Analysys Mason, “Connected Consumer Survey 2018: OTT communication services in Australia and
New Zealand”, slides 7, 10.
74
OECD, “1.13 Mobile data usage per mobile broadband subscription” (December 2018), at
http://www.oecd.org/sti/broadband/broadband-statistics/.
47
Figure 7 Mobile data usage
3.65 According to Consumer NZ’s survey of mobile consumers, 82% of respondents used
mobile broadband in 2018, up from 77% in 2017.
75
3.66 Submissions have generally been unanimous that there has been strong growth in
demand for mobile data, and that this is expected to continue. Chorus noted that
growth in demand for mobile data could be tempered to the extent that prices for
mobile data in New Zealand are high.
76
Spark noted that the amount of data
consumed by mobile customers in New Zealand has increased on average by
around 77% per year since 2010, with significant growth experienced on its
network. Spark also noted that all MNOs have launched large data bundle plans,
including group plans, which are proving to be popular.
77
3.67 2degrees submitted that voice and SMS traffic were likely to decline, as calls and
messaging services become increasingly data-based. This will contribute to demand
for larger data allowances, putting pressure on network capacity and the need for
more spectrum.
78
75
Consumer NZ, Telco Consumer Survey 2018.
76
Chorus submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 7.
77
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 8, 9.
78
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (October 2018), p 14.
48
3.68 Vodafone and Spark also noted that there must be sufficient spectrum made
available to meet the expected growth in mobile data.
79
3.69 Although the average amount of mobile data per connection has been increasing
strongly in New Zealand, New Zealand’s average appears to be relatively low
compared to other OECD countries, as shown in Figure 8. This may in part reflect
relatively high prices for larger bundles of mobile voice and data in New Zealand,
although other factors may also explain this, such as the availability and quality of
fixed broadband networks. As Vodafone has submitted, New Zealand has relatively
high fixed network usage compared to countries such as Finland, and
New Zealanders appear to spend more time connected to WiFi networks on the
mobile devices than other countries.
80
Figure 8 Average mobile data per mobile subscription (December 2018)
81
Investment
3.70 The MNOs have continued to invest in their mobile networks, both in terms of
network upgrades and expansion of coverage. The Government has also
contributed to the expansion of infrastructure in rural areas through the Rural
Broadband Initiative (RBI) and Mobile Black Spot Fund (MBSF).
3.71 NERA submitted that despite rapid growth in mobile and fixed wireless data usage,
Spark’s mobile users have experienced increased quality (in terms of speed, packet
79
Vodafone submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 29; Spark submission on the Issues paper,
(26 October 2018), p 40.
80
Vodafone submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 7.
81
Commerce Commission generated chart based on OECD, “1.13 Mobile data usage per mobile broadband
subscription” (December 2018)”, at http://www.oecd.org/sti/broadband/broadband-statistics/.
49
loss, round trip time). This indicates that Spark has continued to invest in capacity
ahead of demand.
82
3.72 2degrees referred to the investment that it had undertaken to date in product and
network deployment, and that it must continue to invest further, including at the
wholesale level.
83
The MNOs submitted that competition between MNOs has
resulted in increased investment at the network, technology, and services level, as
well as in customer service quality.
84
3.73 We have updated the data on investment in mobile access made by each of the
MNOs, as reported in responses to our annual monitoring questionnaire. This is
shown in Figure 9. Each MNO has in most years invested up to $100 million per
annum in their mobile networks. The investment peaks appear to relate to
Telecom’s investment in its new wideband code-division multiple access (W-CDMA)
network in 2009, and investment by the three MNOs in 700 MHz spectrum in
2015.
85
,
86
Figure 9 Investment in mobile access, by MNO
82
NERA, “Competition in the New Zealand Mobile Market”, (26 October 2018), para 74-84.
83
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 7.
84
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 7; Vodafone submission on the Issues
paper, (26 October 2018), p 3.
85
Telecom’s Annual Report 2009 refers to capital expenditure during 2009 of $300M on its new XT mobile
network.
86
The results of the 700 MHz auction were announced in June 2014, with Spark acquiring 2x20MHz for
$158M; Vodafone acquiring 2x15MHz for $68M; and 2degrees acquiring 2x10MHz for $44M; MBIE, “700
MHz auction: notice of provisional results” (19 June 2014).
50
3.74 A number of submissions argued that regulatory uncertainty can impact the ability
to fund much-needed new capacity, and that mobile operators are facing
investment in 5G technology at a time when mobile revenues are flat and
profitability is constrained.
87
Spark submitted that MNOs are continuing to invest to
meet growing demand and new services, and referred to its investment
programme to augment network capacity and to develop new services.
88
2degrees
also submitted that issues such as the reserve prices and payment terms for new
spectrum will influence investment in network deployment.
89
Profitability
3.75 Several submissions on the Issues Paper referred to profitability. For example,
NERA included the following diagram, and observed that “New Zealand has an
EBITDA
90
margin which is consistently under the world average and this gap is
increasing over time.”
91
Figure 10 EBITDA margin over time
87
Spark submission on the Issues paper(26 October 2018), p 2; 2degrees submission on the Issues paper,
(26 October 2018), p 24.
88
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 9b.
89
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 5.
90
Earnings Before Interest, Tax, Depreciation and Amortisation.
91
NERA “Competition in the New Zealand Mobile Market”, (26 October 2018), para 61.
51
3.76 The NERA submission was not explicit on whether the EBITDA margins reflect pure
mobile operations, or mobile operations that are integrated with fixed-line
operations. Spark has subsequently informed us that the Merrill Lynch EBITDA data
shown in Figure 10 is based on Merrill Lynch estimates of margins for mobile
operations, where segmented results for fixed and mobile operations are not
separately reported.
3.77 However, it is not clear how Merrill Lynch has derived the segmented mobile
margins, and whether its estimates take into account the structure of the
New Zealand telecommunications sector.
92
While the EBITDA margins shown above
may be consistent with a competitive mobile market, the lack of transparency has
limited the weight we placed on the Merrill Lynch results.
3.78 The EBITDA margins shown in Figure 10 above for New Zealand appear to relate to
Vodafone and Spark only and sit at around 35%. The EBITDA and revenues reported
by Trilogy for 2degrees over the last three years is summarised in Table 5. This
indicates an EBITDA margin of 14% in 2015, increasing slightly to 16% in 2017 and
2018.
Table 5 2degrees EBITDA, revenues, and EBITDA margins
93
Year ended 31 December
2015
2016
2017
2018
Revenues (US$’000)
$ 393,055
$ 488,969
$ 520,042
$ 556,410
EBITDA (US$’000)
$ 55,455
$ 80,923
$ 85,307
$ 90,396
EBITDA margin
14%
17%
16%
16%
EBIT (US$’000)
$3,022
$ 21,487
$ 24,502
$24,236
Source: Trilogy International Partners Consolidated Financial Statements as of December 31, 2017 and 2018
3.79 The EBITDA margin for 2degrees (16%) appears to be considerably lower than the
estimated EBITDA margins shown in Figure 10 for the two larger MNOs in
New Zealand. This may in part reflect measurement issues with the Merrill Lynch
92
For example, with structural separation of the fixed-line broadband networks in New Zealand, Spark and
Vodafone purchase wholesale fixed broadband services from Chorus and the other LFCs. This may result in
higher operating expenditure (and lower capital expenditure) for Spark and Vodafone, compared to the
other developed markets shown in Figure 10.
93
See http://www.trilogy-international.com/.
52
estimates.
94
However, it is also likely to reflect differences in scale between the
three MNOs.
95
It may also partly reflect 2degrees’ higher mix of prepaid
subscribers.
Quality of mobile services
3.80 Mobile service quality has several dimensions, including network coverage, mobile
broadband speeds, service availability, and customer service. In terms of
New Zealand’s performance on these, a number of observations can be made.
Network coverage: All MNOs offer mobile services to more than 97% of
population (4G to 95%).
Mobile broadband speeds: Speeds are increasing with the deployment of
4G LTE. In February 2018, OpenSignal reported New Zealand’s 4G
download connection speed of 33 Megabits per second, which was 8th
fastest out of 88 countries.
96
Availability: 3G or 4G availability in New Zealand ranks well, with
OpenSignal ranking New Zealand 6th out of 95 countries.
97
New Zealand’s
ranking in terms of availability of 4G services is lower, although increasing.
In February 2018, OpenSignal reported 4G availability in New Zealand of
69% (65
th
out of 88 countries); in May 2019, 4G availability had increased
to 76% (57
th
out of 87 countries).
98
,
99
Customer service: Consumer NZ’s mobile consumer survey found that the
larger MNOs perform relatively poorly when compared to 2degrees and
Skinny in terms of customer service waiting times and overall customer
satisfaction.
100
94
As noted above, there may be an issue with the segmentation of the fixed and mobile operations of Spark
and Vodafone.
95
This is consistent with the findings of McKinsey that profitability of MNOs correlates strongly with market
share. See McKinsey, “Middle East and Africa: Telecommunications industry at cliff’s edge”, (2016),
Exhibit 14.
96
OpenSignal, “The State of LTE (February 2018)”. OpenSignal is a company that specialises in tracking
mobile network performance from the consumer’s perspective.
97
OpenSignal defines ‘availability’ as the percentage of time that users can connect to the service. This
differs from population or geographic coverage, both of which omit the time dimension.
98
OpenSignal, “The State of Mobile Network Experience: Benchmarking mobile on the eve of the 5G
revolution”, (May 2019).
99
As discussed later, Dense Air intends to use recently acquired spectrum to enhance the coverage of
mobile services in New Zealand.
100
Consumer NZ, Telco Consumer Survey 2018.
53
3.81 A number of parties have submitted on the issue of service quality. According to
2degrees, mobile service quality has a number of dimensions, including those we
identify above. 2degrees supported the monitoring of retail service quality as long
as it avoids unnecessary costs and allows for meaningful comparisons between
operators. 2degrees also noted that monitoring mobile performance is more
complex than fixed-line services due to the greater sharing of resources.
101
3.82 On behalf of Spark, NERA submitted that although the roll-out of 4G started later in
New Zealand compared to Canada, the US, UK, and Australia, New Zealand’s 4G
coverage expanded quickly to reach levels similar to these countries.
102
3.83 Spark and Vodafone have both referred to New Zealand ranking 2
nd
highest in the
GSMA Global Mobile Connectivity Index (GMCI).
103
The GMCI is comprised of four
equally weighted sub-indices, measuring:
mobile infrastructure (including mobile coverage, speeds, spectrum);
affordability of mobile services (mobile tariffs as a % of GDP per capita);
‘consumer readiness’ (literacy, educational enrolment etc); and
content (movies, music, games and sports).
3.84 Vodafone noted that New Zealand ranked 5
th
best in terms of infrastructure, 7
th
in
terms of affordability and 10
th
in terms of network performance.
104
3.85 Vodafone argued that quality metrics should focus on the experience of consumers
rather than arbitrary measures of technology used (such as the Commission’s focus
on 4G availability). Vodafone submitted that the New Zealand mobile networks
perform well, and that fixed-line services are more problematic in terms of
complaints than mobile.
105
3.86 In our view the availability measures relate very much to the experience of
consumers. If a service is not available, it compromises the consumer experience.
The availability metrics provide an additional measure of service quality to
coverage and speed by introducing a time dimension to the assessment of service
quality. However, we agree that availability alone does not provide a full view of
quality.
101
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 14-15.
102
NERA “Competition in the New Zealand Mobile Market”, (26 October 2018), para 69-71.
103
Spark submission, 26 October 2018, para 52; Vodafone submission, (26 October 2018), p 3.
104
Vodafone submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 4.
105
Vodafone submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 30.
54
3.87 Spark submitted that OpenSignal’s 4G availability metric does not measure
coverage as such, but the period of time a device connects to a 4G rather than a 3G
network. According to Spark, this can be influenced by various factors, including the
MNO’s network configuration (to prefer connection to 3G or 4G), service
performance, the extent to which voice calls are delivered using 3G or Voice over
Long Term Evolution (VoLTE), and the capability of the device to connect to various
4G bands.
106
3.88 Spark has also said that its network monitoring indicates that Spark customers
connect to its 4G network for a significantly higher proportion of time than
suggested by OpenSignal.
107
3.89 The reasons for the difference in 4G availability reported by Spark and OpenSignal
are not clear. For example, it might be that Spark performs relatively well in terms
of 4G availability, although we currently do not have 4G availability results for the
other MNOs. As discussed later in the ‘Consumer engagement’ section, access to
information on mobile performance (including data speeds, service availability, and
coverage) is an area that could be improved through the wider consumer and retail
service quality work that we are prioritising.
3.90 Although New Zealand’s mobile networks generally appear to perform well in
terms of most measures of quality, publicly available information on New Zealand’s
overall performance in terms of 4G availability (measuring the proportion of time
that end users can connect to 4G services) ranks relatively poorly.
3.91 As noted by NERA, New Zealand initially lagged behind other countries on 4G
coverage, although currently it is broadly comparable. For example, in Australia
Telstra and Optus report current 4G coverage of 99% and 97% respectively, which
is slightly higher than the 96%-98% reported by the New Zealand MNOs.
108
Consumer satisfaction
3.92 The consumer experience with mobile services is mixed. As shown in Figure 11,
consumers experience fewer problems with mobile telecommunications than with
fixed-line telecommunications but experience more problems with mobile services
than utilities or banking services.
106
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 15-16.
107
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 19.
108
Telstra Annual Report 2018, p 9; and https://www.optus.com.au/shop/mobile/network.
55
Figure 11 Purchasing experiences in the past two years by product or service category
3.93 While fixed-line telecommunications create more complaints than mobile services,
many issues are industry wide (eg, billing, contracts, and sales tactics).
109
3.94 Satisfaction levels with mobile services are above fixed-line telecommunications
services and energy retailers but below banks (see Table 6).
Table 6 Consumer satisfaction by sector
110
Industry
Overall Satisfaction with Suppliers
Largest
Supplier
Best Supplier
Worst Supplier
Industry
Average
Retail - home tech
65%
85%
54%
68%
Retail - mobile
handsets
59%
83%
54%
62%
Banking
54%
87%
54%
60%
Mobile
51%
77%
51%
56%
Fixed-line
telecommunications
49%
68%
43%
51%
Energy
46%
66%
46%
51%
Source: Derived from Consumer NZ (Telecommunications 2018, Banking 2019, Retail 2018, Energy 2019).
111
109
Complaints made to the Commerce Commission.
110
Red numbers show the lowest industry in each satisfaction category, green numbers the highest. % is the
percentage of respondents who said they were very satisfied with their service provider.
111
Results for the banking, energy and telco sectors are from Consumer NZ’s nationally representative
surveys of the New Zealand population; results for the retail home tech and mobile handset categories are
from Consumer NZ member surveys.
56
Findings on the development of the mobile market
F1
Market shares among the three national MNOs have become more evenly
balanced over time, particularly in the prepaid and residential on-account
segments.
F2
Ongoing investment in the mobile networks has seen all three MNOs investing
in new generations of mobile technology and 2degrees completing the roll-out
of its national network.
F3
All three national MNOs are reporting profits, although profit margins vary,
reflecting differences in market share and mix of customers.
F4
The three national MNOs appear to perform well on most technical measures
of quality, although there is some evidence that the quality of coverage for 4G
services (as measured by availability) may be relatively low compared to other
countries.
F5
Prices of mobile services have been falling. Prices for low and medium usage
bundles compare well with other OECD countries. Prices for higher usage
bundles remain relatively expensive, especially when compared with Australia,
although recent market developments have resulted in ongoing innovation and
improved value for consumers in relation to higher usage bundles.
F6
Usage of mobile calls and in particular mobile data has continued to increase in
recent years, with the amount of mobile data used per subscriber more than
doubling over the last two years. Although average data usage appears to be
relatively low compared to other countries, this may be due to a number of
factors, including pricing of higher usage bundles and the availability and
quality of fixed networks (including WiFi hotspots) in New Zealand.
57
Our views on the key issues in the mobile market
3.95 As discussed in the above sections, competition in the mobile market has been
developing to the point where there are now three national MNOs, as well as a
small number of MVNOs. Further MVNO-based entry has also been announced.
The performance of the mobile market has generally improved in terms of
delivering competitive outcomes to consumers, through lower prices, increasing
quality, and greater choice of services.
3.96 Based on the above, as well as information provided in submissions received
throughout the course of this study, there are three key issues which are likely to
influence the further development of competition in the mobile market going
forward. These issues relate to spectrum, MVNOs, and consumer engagement.
Together these will potentially have a significant influence on conditions for
competition in the mobile market.
3.97 We briefly discuss the importance of each of these issues below, before turning to
each of them in more detail in Chapter 4.
Spectrum
3.98 Radio spectrum is a critical input used in the deployment of a mobile network. The
type and amount of spectrum held by the MNOs will affect the way in which they
deploy their networks, and the capacity and services they can offer to retail and
wholesale customers.
3.99 The three MNOs currently have asymmetric holdings of spectrum, particularly in
the sub-1 GHz bands and in some of the higher frequency bands. 2degrees
submitted that it holds 18.5% of key mobile spectrum, compared to 40% held by
Spark and 30% held by Vodafone.
112
3.100 According to 2degrees, it has been able to compete and expand since its entry,
although its ability to continue to do so will depend on acquiring sufficient new
spectrum, particularly due to the rapid increase in demand for mobile data.
Throughout this study, Vodafone and Spark have also referred to the importance of
adequate spectrum being released in the 3.5 GHz band to support the development
of 5G networks.
3.101 We note that 2degrees has now largely completed the roll-out of its national
network, for which it has incurred significant fixed and sunk costs. As long as each
of the MNOs has sufficient capacity, which will be influenced by their spectrum
112
2degrees submission on the Issues Paper, (October 2018). The balance of 11% was held by Blue Reach at
the time of 2degrees’ submission on the Issues Paper.
58
holdings, they are likely to face strong incentives to compete at both the retail and
the wholesale level.
3.102 The allocation of spectrum will continue to have a very important influence on
competitive conditions in downstream markets, including the mobile market, and
on how competition evolves in the future.
113
MVNOs
3.103 During this study, we have sought to better understand the performance of the
retail market, and whether we should consider intervening to promote additional
MVNO-based entry. If competition in the retail market is found to be delivering
poor consumer outcomes which are not expected to improve, it may be
appropriate to consider intervening at the wholesale level (such as through
regulation of MVNO access) to promote entry. Any such intervention would need to
be compared to what would happen in the absence of regulation for example,
whether competition at the wholesale level is likely to lead to sustainable MVNO-
based entry.
3.104 In this regard, we have sought views on whether competitive conditions at the
wholesale level have changed as a result of 2degrees having completed its national
network, and how wholesale competition is expected to evolve over the next two-
three years.
3.105 In response, a number of parties have provided extensive submissions throughout
this study on competitive conditions at the wholesale level. Several submissions
noted that MVNOs have brought a range of benefits in other countries, such as
greater variety of mobile services, price competition, and increased options for
bundling of mobile services with other services which in turn may be of growing
importance for the effectiveness of competition in telecommunications markets.
3.106 Submissions from Spark, Vodafone and 2degrees generally claim that they are
increasingly competing to attract MVNO business, pointing to the entry of
Warehouse Mobile as well as the (then) anticipated new entry by Trustpower and
Kogan Mobile.
3.107 For such MVNO-based competitors, the availability of MVNO access on reasonable
terms will influence their ability to expand and evolve in retail markets. Until
recently, there appears to have been limited competition between MNOs to host
113
The importance of competition objectives for spectrum allocation has been recognised in many overseas
jurisdictions. See for example, BEREC, “BEREC report on practices on spectrum authorization, award
procedures and coverage obligations with a view to considering their suitability to 5G”, (6 December
2018); ACCC “Allocation limits advice for the 3.6 GHz spectrum allocation”, (July 2018).
59
MVNOs, and this may have resulted in commercial MVNO agreements which have
not been conducive to MVNO entry and expansion.
3.108 However, there has been some evidence provided in submissions and elsewhere
that the level of wholesale activity has been increasing in recent years. Some
parties have submitted that this increased activity at the wholesale level may be a
result of this study. While the scrutiny brought about by this study may have had
some effect in stimulating wholesale activity, we have also considered whether
sustainable wholesale competition has emerged as a result of 2degrees completing
its national network and becoming more active in pursuing wholesale opportunities
and encouraging MVNOs on its network.
Consumer engagement
3.109 The level of engagement by consumers is an important source of competitive
pressure on suppliers of mobile services. An important part of this study has been
to better understand the nature and effectiveness of consumer engagement in the
mobile market, and whether consumers face any issues in comparing and switching
between retail mobile offers.
3.110 Although submissions have not revealed significant issues for consumer
engagement in the mobile market, we remain of the view that it is important to
better understand the extent to which mobile consumers are engaged and active,
and what is important to consumers when choosing a mobile service provider.
3.111 The ability of different consumers to review their needs and to periodically
compare and switch between retail mobile offers will affect expansion conditions
within the mobile market and the incentives for mobile providers to compete. The
ability of a mobile service provider to enter and expand in market segments will
affect its competitive position. This is because the number and the mix of
customers are likely to influence a mobile provider’s costs, profitability, and its
ability to continue to invest in its network.
60
Chapter 4 Key issues we identified
Purpose and structure of this chapter
4.1 During this study, we identified three key issues which may influence the
performance of the mobile market in delivering competitive outcomes for mobile
consumers in New Zealand:
spectrum;
MVNO access; and
mobile consumer engagement.
4.2 This chapter sets out our more detailed exploration of these three key issues,
discussing them and presenting our findings and actions.
Spectrum
Introduction
4.3 This section sets out our analysis and findings on radio spectrum allocation
including:
the importance of spectrum for competition between existing MNOs;
the importance of spectrum for new entry;
other obligations and payment terms for spectrum allocation; and
a summary of our views on spectrum.
Spectrum and competition between existing MNOs
4.4 Radio spectrum is a critical input used in the deployment of a mobile network. The
type and amount of spectrum that is allocated to MNOs will affect the way in which
they deploy their networks and the services that can be offered in downstream
markets, including wholesale and retail markets. The existing spectrum holdings of
the three MNOs are summarised in Figure 12.
61
Figure 12 Spectrum holdings
4.5 The asymmetries in existing spectrum holdings between the MNOs varies across
spectrum bands. For example:
in the sub 1 GHz bands, Spark holds a total of 70 MHz spectrum
(700 MHz/850 MHz), Vodafone holds a total of 60 MHz spectrum
(700 MHz/900 MHz), and 2degrees holds a total of 40 MHz spectrum
(700 MHz/900 MHz);
in the 1800 MHz band, each of the MNOs currently hold 50 MHz spectrum;
in the 2100 MHz band, Spark and 2degrees each hold 30 MHz, while
Vodafone holds 50 MHz; and
in the 3.5 GHz band, Vodafone currently holds 56 MHz (which it will use for
its 5G services from December 2019), and Spark holds 14 MHz
4.6 As discussed below:
the existing management rights in the 1800 MHz and 2100 MHz bands are
due to expire in 2021. The Government has recently announced its
decisions on the proposed renewal of management rights within these
bands; and
62
the existing management rights in the 3.5 GHz band are due to expire in
2022.
114
The management rights for the use of spectrum in this band
beyond 2022 are due to be allocated in 2020.
4.7 The spectrum held by Spark and to a lesser extent Vodafone in some of the higher
frequency bands (particularly the 2300-2600 MHz bands) has enabled them to
launch fixed wireless broadband services while minimising disruption to their
mobile customers. For example, the number of subscribers to Spark’s fixed wireless
broadband service increased from 84,000 subscribers as of June 2017, to 140,000
subscribers as of June 2019.
115
4.8 The ability to offer fixed wireless services may have been a factor in Trustpower’s
decision to sign an MVNO agreement with Spark. Many of Trustpower’s rural
customers are unlikely to have access to fibre services in the near future, and these
customers can be served using fixed wireless services.
116
4.9 In March 2019, the Government announced its decision on the renewal of radio
spectrum management rights in the 1800 MHz and 2100 MHz bands. These rights
are due to expire in 2021. As a result:
117
in the 1800 MHz band, of the 50 MHz currently held by each of 2degrees,
Spark and Vodafone, 40 MHz is proposed to be renewed; and
in the 2100 MHz band, all of the existing rights held by 2degrees (30 MHz),
Spark (30 MHz), and Vodafone (50 MHz) are proposed to be renewed.
118
4.10 A number of submitters agreed that significant disparities in spectrum holdings are
likely to distort competition at both the retail and the wholesale level. For example,
Sky said that effective spectrum allocation “lies at the heart of a competitive
mobile market.
119
Trustpower and Spark agreed that spectrum is a critical input,
and that significant asymmetries in holdings can affect competition.
120
Vocus said it
114
The current holdings of 3.5 GHz spectrum shown in Figure 12 are in the lower part of the 3.5 GHz band.
RSM are currently inviting expressions of interest for a proposed short-term allocation of spectrum in the
upper portion of the 3.5 GHz band to support the deployment of 5G services between 2020-2022.
115
Spark New Zealand FY19 Results Summary, p 35.
116
Trustpower media release, “Trustpower pleased to announce wireless broadband and mobile services on
the way for customers”, (20 November 2018).
117
Government media release, “Spectrum rights renewed in 3G and 4G bands”, (12 March 2019), available at
https://www.beehive.govt.nz/release/spectrum-rights-renewed-3g-and-4g-bands.
118
An additional 10 MHz in the 2100 MHz band held by Telstra is not to be renewed.
119
Sky submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 2.1.
120
Trustpower submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 3; Spark submission on the
Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 1.
63
supported a rebalancing of spectrum to bolster the ability of 2degrees to compete
at both the retail and wholesale levels.
121
4.11 Vodafone also agreed that spectrum is a key input that will continue to have a very
important influence on competitive conditions in downstream markets.
122
According to Vodafone, compared to other countries, New Zealand has a significant
amount of spectrum allocated to the MNOs, which has lowered the costs of
network deployment and reduced the impact of other challenges (such as covering
complex terrain and a small population).
123
4.12 Vodafone submitted that existing spectrum holdings have been driven by
competition, allocation rules set by the Government, and commercial decisions by
operators (citing the example of the 700 MHz spectrum allocation process, in which
2degrees did not seek to acquire the full block that was available to it). According
to Vodafone, the resulting spectrum holdings reflect the market shares of each
MNO, with 2degrees holding more spectrum on a per subscriber basis than
Vodafone and Spark.
124
4.13 2degrees holds a smaller block of sub-1 GHz spectrum, and although its parent has
stated that it has been able to compete with the other MNOs,
125
2degrees has
submitted that its ability to continue to compete and expand depends on acquiring
new spectrum.
126
According to 2degrees submission, existing disparities in
spectrum should not be widened, and in particular:
127
2degrees should be able to acquire at least the same amount of 3.5 GHz
spectrum as the other MNOs. Each MNO should be able to acquire a
minimum of 80 MHz,
128
although 100 MHz would be ideal, allowing
optimal long-term competitive delivery of wireless services; and
2degrees should be able to acquire the unused 2100 MHz held by Telstra.
4.14 In responding to Vodafone on spectrum holdings, 2degrees submitted that
Vodafone’s position would lock the market into a ‘current state’, with 2degrees’
121
Vocus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 38.
122
Vodafone submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 9.
123
Vodafone submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 3, 10.
124
Vodafone submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 13.
125
Trilogy International Partners, “Annual Information Form for the Year Ended December 31, 2017”,
(21 March 2018), p 16.
126
2degrees submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (June 2019), p 6.
127
2degrees submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (June 2019), p 9-10.
128
2degrees submission on the Issues Paper (October 2018), p 23.
64
market share being frozen by lower spectrum holdings. 2degrees submitted that
this would not support ongoing competition at the retail or wholesale level.
129
2degrees also noted that at the time of the 700 MHz spectrum auction in 2014,
2degrees was capital constrained. At the time, 2degrees was yet to record a profit,
and was still deploying its national network and making substantial payments for
national roaming.
4.15 In allocating spectrum, it is important that consideration is given to the likely
competitive effects of any allocation. While we recognise that there may be
competing objectives that the Crown will likely need to balance, we consider that
promotion of competition should be an important consideration in spectrum
allocation for the long-term benefit of New Zealanders.
4.16 The competition impacts of spectrum acquisitions can be considered in two ways:
under the Commerce Act through the merger clearance process and the
ability for the Commission to undertake merger enforcement
investigations under section 47 of the Commerce Act; and
through tools applied as a matter of Government policy as part of auction
design to promote competition, including setting the reserve price for
spectrum allocations, spectrum caps (or acquisition limits), ‘use it or lose
it’ provisions, implementation requirements, and payment terms.
130
4.17 In considering whether an acquisition (including renewals) of spectrum would be
likely to substantially lessen competition under section 47 of the Commerce Act, we
look at the impact of the acquisition on telecommunications markets. This is a
relative test that examines competition with and without the acquisition to see
whether competition would likely be substantially lessened as a result of the
acquisition. The competitive impact may not only depend on the particular band of
spectrum being acquired, but also on holdings in other spectrum bands which may
be a close substitute.
4.18 The use of mechanisms such as spectrum caps as part of an auction for new
spectrum allocations may seek to further promote competitive conditions. RSM has
been consulting on the key issues surrounding the allocation of further spectrum
(initially in the 3.5 GHz band) to support the deployment of 5G services, including
the use of spectrum caps.
131
The MNOs have submitted, both to RSM and
129
2degrees cross-submission on Preliminary Findings paper, (July 2019), p 3-4.
130
These tools are discussed in the recent Cabinet Paper on 5G spectrum. See Cabinet Paper, “Allocation of
Radio Spectrum for 5G Mobile”, (27 February 2019), para 49, 56, 76 and 78.
131
RSM, “Preparing for 5G in New Zealand: Discussion document”, (March 2018); “Discussion document:
Technical Arrangements of the 3.5 GHz Band”, (June 2019).
65
throughout this study, that they should each be able to acquire 80-100 MHz of
3.5 GHz spectrum.
4.19 We consider that a key feature of the allocation process for this spectrum will be
the setting of acquisition limits that prevent any party or parties from dominating
spectrum holdings and distorting competition in downstream markets. The
Minister of Broadcasting, Communications and Digital Media (the Minister) has
recommended to the Cabinet Economic Development Committee that a limit be set
on the amount of national 5G spectrum given to any one operator, “to prevent
stronger players in the market from shutting out weaker incumbents or potential
new entrants”.
132
4.20 In its advice to the Australian Minister for Communications on spectrum limits in
relation to 3.6 GHz spectrum, the ACCC noted it may be appropriate to take into
account existing holdings of spectrum in other bands when considering how much
new spectrum a party should be able to acquire.
133
4.21 In commenting on spectrum caps to be applied in the upcoming 3.5 GHz auction,
Spark said it would be concerned if an aggregate spectrum cap were to be
applied.
134
Spark submitted that any conclusions on spectrum asymmetries should
consider utilisation of existing holdings, and Sparks core spectrum holdings are
heavily utilised. As a result, Spark will need to invest in either additional spectrum
or more sites. According to Spark, the latter is becoming more challenging due to
community concerns, and so if Spark cannot acquire the spectrum it needs, the
result will be capacity constraints, with implications for consumers and
competition.
135
4.22 We note Spark’s submission on the importance for Spark of acquiring enough
spectrum, otherwise network capacity will be compromised as it reaches spectrum
saturation, and as it faces challenges building more sites. While this may be the
case, it is likely to equally apply to the other MNOs, and, in particular, 2degrees due
to its existing spectrum holdings. If existing asymmetries are widened significantly,
such constraints are likely to be exacerbated. For example, we have already seen
that 2degrees has not yet launched fixed wireless services, and this may be due to
its lack of higher capacity spectrum.
132
Cabinet Paper, “Allocation of Radio Spectrum for 5G Mobile”, (12 December 2018 - released 27 February
2019), para 5, 27, 49.
133
ACCC, “Allocation limits advice for the 3.6 GHz spectrum allocation”, (July 2018), p 2.
134
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 26.
135
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 30-31.
66
4.23 Spark also submitted that spectrum bands have different characteristics (such as
coverage vs capacity), and that not all bands are strong substitutes.
136
At present,
only the 3.5 GHz band has widespread equipment availability and large bandwidths
available to support 5G services. According to Spark, existing holdings can have
little practical relevance when considering 3.5 GHz spectrum acquisitions.
137
4.24 However, Spark has previously stated that different spectrum bands are readily
substitutable. In its application for clearance to acquire 2300 MHz spectrum, Spark
made the following statement:
138
Spectrum in the 2300MHz and other spectrum bands made available for mobile and
broadband services (including the 700MHz, 850MHz, 900MHz, 1800MHz, 2100MHz,
2500/2600MHz and 3400MHz bands) are readily substitutable with each other for
the provision of LTE FWA services.
4.25 Substitutability between spectrum bands is an important consideration when
looking at the implications for competition of a spectrum acquisition. This may be
particularly relevant for the allocation of 3.5 GHz spectrum and the renewals of
1800 MHz and 2100 MHz spectrum.
Spectrum and new entry
4.26 As discussed above, access to spectrum is important for existing operators to
compete in downstream retail and wholesale markets. Access to spectrum is also
required for new entrants.
4.27 In addition to looking at differences in the current spectrum holdings of the three
existing MNOs, we have considered whether parties other than the existing three
MNOs should be able to participate in any future allocation of spectrum. This
includes potential new MNOs, as well as other parties such as regional service
providers.
4.28 Based on our analysis of the performance of the retail mobile market in
New Zealand, there does not appear to be a strong case for regulatory intervention
to promote a fourth MNO to enter the New Zealand market.
136
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 33.
137
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 37.
138
Spark, “Notice Seeking Clearance of a Business Acquisition Pursuant to Section 66 of the Commerce Act
1986”, 18 December 2015, para 8.7.
67
4.29 Several parties agreed that there is not a case for regulatory intervention to
support a fourth MNO. For example:
2degrees submitted that a fourth national MNO is unlikely to be
sustainable in a market with falling margins, in which network build is
costly, and in which significant ongoing investment is required. 2degrees
noted that new entry is emerging in the form of MVNOs as a result of
wholesale competition;
139
Covec submitted that it would be challenging to build a fourth mobile
network in New Zealand and estimated a break-even market share of 10%
of revenues would need to be achieved relatively quickly.
140
Covec noted
that a fourth MNO would further fragment spectrum holdings.
141
TUANZ indicated that a fourth MNO was unlikely due to the capital costs
required to build coverage across a geographically challenging and small
market.
142
4.30 However, the upcoming 3.5 GHz spectrum allocation should not preclude the
possibility of new entry if investors see a potential business case to acquire and use
spectrum. In our view, any entry decision should be up to investors, who should be
able to determine the merits of a business case for entry. Reserving the new
spectrum solely for the use of the existing three MNOs would erect an absolute
barrier to entry and would preclude the possibility of new entry into downstream
markets.
4.31 A number of parties agreed. For example, Spark submitted that the design of
spectrum auctions should not prevent possible entry from new operators.
143
4.32 Such entry may not necessarily be in the form of a fourth MNO that would compete
against the existing MNOs. For example, in November 2018 Dense Air acquired
70 MHz of spectrum in the 2600 MHz band in New Zealand.
144
Dense Air intends to
use the spectrum to offer network extension services to the existing MNOs, by
using small-cell technology at the edge of cells to enhance coverage.
139
2degrees submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (June 2019), p 8.
140
Covec submission on the Issues paper, (24 October 2018), para 62.
141
Covec submission on the Issues paper, (24 October 2018), p 8, 9.
142
TUANZ submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (30 June 2019), para 16.
143
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 25.
144
http://denseair.net/dense-air-acquires-2-6-ghz-spectrum-assets-in-new-zealand/.
68
4.33 Dense Air’s entry is more complementary to the existing MNOs, as Dense Air does
not intend to compete with existing mobile operators at the retail level.
145
The
Dense Air business model is targeted at enhancing MNOs coverage and capacity
using Dense Air’s licenced spectrum to in-fill coverage gaps in urban areas and
extend capacity weak spots in more rural areas where it is not economically
efficient for MNOs to deploy this additional infrastructure themselves.
4.34 Potential interest in upcoming spectrum allocations in New Zealand has emerged
from regional wireless internet service providers (WISPs). InternetNZ highlighted
the importance of non-mobile operators such as WISPs being able to compete for
spectrum rights.
146
According to InternetNZ, the issues raised by the Wireless
Internet Service Providers Association of New Zealand (WISPA NZ) including the
prospect that spectrum currently used by WISPs may be transferred to the MNOs
are particularly relevant.
147
4.35 It appears that the WISPs will continue to have access to spectrum in the 3.5 GHz
band, although the precise details of WISP allocations are yet to be confirmed. In its
March 2018 discussion document on 5G spectrum, RSM referred to a total of 280
MHz of spectrum in the 3.5 GHz band as being available for 5G networks.
148
4.36 In February 2019, the Minister of Broadcasting, Communications and Digital Media
said that officials have since identified that 390 MHz of spectrum could be allocated
in the 3.5 GHz band, which could in principle be sufficient to meet the needs of up
to four national network operators, as well as regional service providers (WISPs).
149
The amount of 3.5 GHz spectrum actually available for direct allocation will also
depend on Treaty of Waitangi policy, and guard band considerations.
150
4.37 The Minister also noted that the allocation of 3.5 GHz spectrum is expected to take
place in 2020, with the associated rights to use the spectrum to apply from 2022.
151
145
http://denseair.net/dense-air-acquires-2-6-ghz-spectrum-assets-in-new-zealand/.
146
InternetNZ submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 13.
147
InternetNZ submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 11.
148
RSM “Preparing for 5G in New Zealand: Discussion document”, (March 2018), p 5.
149
Cabinet Paper, “Allocation of Radio Spectrum for 5G Mobile”, (12 December 2018 - released
27 February 2019), para 5, 27.
150
Cabinet Paper, “Allocation of Radio Spectrum for 5G Mobile”, (12 December 2018 - released
27 February 2019), para 27.
151
Cabinet Paper, “Allocation of Radio Spectrum for 5G Mobile”, (12 December 2018 - released
27 February 2019), para 6.
69
Other obligations and payment terms for spectrum allocation
4.38 Several parties have commented on whether obligations should be attached to the
allocation of spectrum. Such obligations could include the following:
obligations to offer wholesale access to third parties;
obligations to ensure the spectrum is used, rather than hoarded.
4.39 Wholesale access obligations have been supported by several parties, including
Trustpower,
152
TUANZ,
153
and Nova.
154
4.40 As discussed further in the MVNO section below, we do not see a strong case for
regulatory intervention in respect of MVNO access. Our reasons for this that the
downstream retail market in which mobile services are supplied to end users is
performing reasonably well, and that competition is also emerging at the wholesale
level apply both to the case for ex ante regulation (such as through the addition
of an MVNO access service to Schedule 1 of the Telecommunications Act) and the
case for including an obligation attached to spectrum rights to offer wholesale
access to third parties.
4.41 We also note that although Red Dawn Consulting (RDC) flagged a wholesale
obligation as a potential option to consider, RDC noted a potential disadvantage is
that such an obligation may have an adverse impact on the extent and timing of 5G
deployments. This could result in a significant detriment for end users. RDC also
noted that it is uncommon for national regulators to attach wholesale obligations
to spectrum, with a small number of exceptions (Germany and Romania).
4.42 Several submitters have referred to the risk that spectrum might be hoarded rather
than used to roll out services. For example, InternetNZ has expressed concerns that
spectrum is a scarce resource that is allocated for periods of up to 20 years, which
can result in hoarding.
155
2degrees also submitted that it will be important to have
meaningful but realistic implementation conditions to dissuade speculative
bidding.
156
152
Trustpower submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 23.
153
TUANZ submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (30 June 2019), para 42.
154
Nova submission on the Preliminary Findings paper’ (28 June 2019), para 8.
155
InternetNZ submission on the Issues Paper’ (26 October 2018), p 9.
156
2degrees submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (June 2019), p 8.
70
4.43 We support the inclusion of ‘use it or lose itobligations on parties acquiring
spectrum. In this regard, we note that the recommendations of the Minister of
Broadcasting, Communications and Digital Media to the Cabinet Economic
Development Committee in February 2019 propose to include obligations to use
spectrum allocated in the 3.5 GHz band. Such obligations are to ensure that
spectrum is actually used, and to discourage hoarding and speculation, which could
also have an adverse impact on competition. The requirements proposed by the
Minister would require the recipients of the spectrum rights to implement a
network within:
157
five years in the case of a national network, extendable to seven years on
payment of a sum to be decided; and
two years in the case of a regional or local network.
4.44 We also note that the February 2019 Cabinet Paper on 5G spectrum refers to the
option of allowing recipients of spectrum to pay for the spectrum by instalments,
and that the Minister will consider the case for instalments as part of the design of
the 3.5 GHz auction.
158
This approach could reduce the barriers for new entrants or
allow parties to secure viable spectrum allocations.
4.45 We will continue to engage with MBIE on the design of future spectrum auctions
including the 5G auction.
157
Cabinet Paper, “Allocation of Radio Spectrum for 5G Mobile”, (12 December 2018 - released 27 February
2019), para 5, 27 , 56.
158
Cabinet Paper, “Allocation of Radio Spectrum for 5G Mobile”, (12 December 2018 - released
27 February 2019), para 78.
71
Findings on spectrum
F7
Spectrum is a scarce and critical input into the supply of mobile services.
Significant asymmetries in spectrum holdings (including in terms of the
amount and type of spectrum held) can affect competition in the mobile
market. The design of future allocation processes for spectrum should have
regard to such asymmetries. In setting limits on the amount of spectrum that
may be acquired, it may also be appropriate to have regard to existing holdings
in other bands which represent a substitute for the spectrum being auctioned
or allocated.
F8
We do not believe there is a case for regulatory intervention to promote a
fourth national MNO to enter the market. However, the design of the
upcoming 3.5 GHz spectrum allocation process should not preclude new
parties (including parties who may complement or compete with the existing
MNOs) from obtaining spectrum.
F9
We do not believe that there is a strong case for including a condition on
spectrum rights that requires wholesale access to be offered to third parties.
72
MVNOs
Introduction
4.46 This section sets out our analysis and findings on MVNOs, including:
a brief outline of the potential benefits that MVNOs can bring for
consumers of mobile services;
describing the types of MVNO operating models and the gross margins
expected for each type of MVNO model;
examining the emergence of competition at the wholesale level for MVNO
services in New Zealand; and
summarising our findings with respect to MVNOs.
Potential benefits to consumers from MVNOs
4.47 MVNO entry can provide consumers with more choice of standalone mobile
services as well as bundles that include mobile and other services. MVNOs can offer
price competition and some service innovation, product differentiation, and a more
flexible set of tariff arrangements which may better meet the needs of specific
customer niches. MVNOs often enter to target niche segments of the market that
traditional MNOs may not be willing or able to serve.
4.48 There are also benefits to consumers from being able to purchase bundled services.
Fixed-line service providers can use an MVNO model to provide bundled offers. For
example:
Vocus has been offering discounts to residential customers who purchase
both a fixed-line broadband service, and a mobile service. For example, its
Slingshot brand offers a monthly discount as well as upfront credits
(currently $300) when a customer signs up to any broadband and mobile
plan for 12 months;
159
Trustpower, when it launches, intends offering its fixed broadband and
electricity customers the option of acquiring mobile services in its
bundles.
160
Nova has also recently acquired an MVNO (MegaTEL), enabling
159
Slingshot website accessed September 2019.
160
Trustpower media release, “Trustpower pleased to announce wireless broadband and mobile services on
the way for customers”, (20 November 2018).
73
it to offer mobile services along with its energy and fixed-line services;
161
and
WISPA NZ have indicated that there would be strategic value for WISPs in
being able to offer a full-service bundle, including mobile, to rural
consumers.
162
4.49 In submissions on the Preliminary Findings, there were a range of views on the
importance of MVNO-based competition. Trustpower submitted that MVNO
competition is important, and that the Commission may have taken a narrow view
of the role that MVNOs can play in promoting competition. According to
Trustpower, while some MVNOs may complement MNOs in serving customer
niches, broader MVNO models have been successful in other countries in delivering
cheaper prices, increased product variety, and consumer choice. Trustpower said
that there is no reason why this cannot happen in New Zealand, as long as MVNO
access arrangements don't limit the ability of MVNOs to compete and innovate.
163
4.50 Nova said that the ability of non-MNO retailers to gain wholesale access to mobile
services on reasonable terms is crucial to ensuring sufficient competition and
choice in both fixed and mobile markets.
164
TUANZ submitted that as a fourth MNO
is unlikely to be sustainable, increased competition will have to come from
MVNOs.
165
4.51 2degrees expects new MVNOs to offer additional choice to consumers, although
submitted that the small size of the New Zealand market limits the scope for MVNO
expansion compared to other countries. 2degrees also noted that there is already
strong price competition between MNOs, and that MVNOs may face challenges in
gaining the scale required to justify investment in fuller MVNO models.
166
4.52 Vodafone and Spark questioned whether greater MVNO participation in the retail
market would actually improve consumer outcomes. According to Vodafone,
consumers in New Zealand are currently getting a good deal on mobile services,
and there is no evidence that MVNOs would add anything.
167
Spark referred to
NERA’s finding that there is no evidence of a link between MVNO market share and
161
Nova submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 3.
162
WISPA NZ submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 2.
163
Trustpower submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 4-5.
164
Nova submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 6.
165
TUANZ submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (30 June 2019), para 26.
166
2degrees submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (June 2019), p 3, 10.
167
Vodafone submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 16.
74
improved consumer outcomes (such as download speeds, data usage, or 4G
uptake).
168
4.53 In considering the benefits that MVNO-based entry brings for consumers, the
performance of the retail market in which mobile services are delivered to
consumers is relevant. If the retail market was found to be delivering poor
outcomes to consumers, the benefits from promoting additional entry or expansion
in the retail market, including through MVNOs, are likely to be greater.
4.54 In Chapter 3, we examined the development of mobile services and competition in
New Zealand, based on a range of key indicators. These include indicators relating
to the structure of the mobile market (including market shares and entry
conditions), as well as performance indicators such as pricing, investment, and
service quality. We found that the retail market continues to develop and deliver
increasingly competitive outcomes for mobile consumers.
4.55 Trustpower noted that in other countries with a similar population to New Zealand,
such as Denmark, Austria, Norway, and Ireland, there are a larger number of
MVNOs.
169
However, while other countries have a larger number of MVNOs, we are
ultimately interested in the long-term benefit of end users of telecommunications
services, including mobile services, in New Zealand. In this regard, we have looked
at the performance of the retail market for mobile services in terms of delivering
competitive outcomes for consumers.
4.56 There appears to be mixed evidence of the benefits brought by MVNOs. This likely
depends on the extent of competition between MNOs and the terms and
conditions under which MVNOs operate in different jurisdictions.
4.57 We remain of the view that MVNO-based entry can bring a range of potential
competitive benefits, including offering greater choice, service innovation
(including bundles of mobile services and other services), and more competitive
pricing. As noted earlier, MVNOs often target niche segments of the market that
traditional MNOs may not be willing or able to serve.
4.58 However, MVNOs are dependent on their host network, and this may limit the
extent to which they can differentiate their offerings from those of their host MNO,
depending on the terms and conditions of access.
170
168
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 51d.
169
Trustpower cross-submission on Preliminary Findings paper, (19 July 2019), p 4.
170
The ACCC has also stated that it considers MVNOs to provide a limited constraint on the MNOs in
Australia, “particularly as they rely on purchasing wholesale end-to-end mobile services from MNOs.”
75
MVNO operating models and margins
4.59 MVNOs typically provide the same or similar retail services as a traditional MNO.
They purchase capacity from an MNO, then in turn offer services to their own
customer base and acquire new customers from MNOs or other MVNOs.
4.60 There are different types of MVNO operating models. These are typically described
as ranging from a licensed reseller, which is the minimalist form of MVNO, through
intermediate models, to a ‘full’ MVNO (sometimes also referred to as ‘thick’
MVNOs). Under a full MVNO model, the MVNO invests in more of the key
components of a mobile network apart from radio spectrum. The MVNO models
offer the MNO the opportunity to generate revenue from spare network capacity.
4.61 Figure 13 illustrates the different MVNO operating models.
Figure 13 MVNO operating models
4.62 The number of key components carried out by the MVNO grows for each
progressive model, as does the expected margin discount typically offered by the
MNO.
171
This is because the level of investment required by the MVNO increases as
it moves from a simple reseller with minimal investment through to a ‘full’ MVNO,
where the MVNO owns and operates core network elements. As a result, the
ACCC, “Statement of Issues TPG Telecom proposed merger with Vodafone”, (13 December 2018),
para 121 and 190.
171
The discounts expected under each of the MVNO operating models are further discussed below.
76
division of components between the MVNO and the host MNO will vary across the
operating models, and the level of discount will reflect this division.
4.63 Table 7 below shows the typical range of gross margins (representing discounts off
retail prices) expected for each of the MVNO models illustrated in Figure 13. These
ranges are taken from the experience of RDC and its involvement in approximately
one hundred MVNO arrangements globally.
172
Table 7 MVNO operating models and gross margin
MVNO Model
Gross Margin Range
Licensed Reseller
10-20%
Service Provider
20-35%
Light MVNO
35-55%
Full MVNO
45-70%
Source: RDC “MVNO Landscape: Global perspectives and New Zealand Applications” April 2019.
4.64 We note that the European Commission cleared a 4-to-3 merger in Austria on the
condition that the merged entity meet a number of conditions to facilitate new
entry, including providing wholesale access to MVNOs. The pricing terms of that
wholesale access included a discount of 25% off the retail price (retail-minus
discount).
173
4.65 We understand that the model operated by the Warehouse Mobile would sit
towards the left-hand side of Figure 13 (Licensed reseller). Vocus and Trustpower
appear to sit somewhere between Service Provider and Light MVNOs.
174
4.66 As RDC has noted, the potential growth of MVNO models may be moderated by the
relatively small size of the New Zealand market and the set-up costs associated
with MVNO operating models. According to RDC:
for an MVNO based on a licensed reseller model, set-up costs for the
MVNO are low;
for a light MVNO, set-up costs incurred by the MVNO can be between
$1 million and $2 million; and
172
RDC, “MVNO landscape: Global perspectives and New Zealand Applications”, (24 April 2019), p 12-13.
173
European Commission Decision, Case No M.6497 Hutchison 3G Austria / Orange Austria, (12 December
2012), p 165.
174
Informed by RDC, “MVNO Landscape report” (24 April 2019), p 30.
77
for a full MVNO, set-up costs incurred by the MVNO can be between
$2 million and $3 million.
4.67 RDC suggest that the full MVNO model is unlikely to be justified for a market the
size of New Zealand.
175
4.68 Spark and Vodafone agreed with RDC’s view that given the small size of the
New Zealand market, there may be limited opportunities for MVNOs, and that such
opportunities are likely to be at the reseller end of the spectrum shown in Figure 13
above.
176
4.69 We note RDC’s view that the light MVNO model is likely to be appropriate for
New Zealand:
177
In NZ, we suggest that the Light MVNO model is the most appropriate. The licenced
reseller and service provider models are unlikely to provide sufficient margins, nor the
ability to facilitate service differentiation for potential new entrants.
4.70 Trustpower and Vocus submitted that it is important for MVNOs to have the
opportunity to negotiate access for thicker MVNO models, to give them greater
control and deeper access to the mobile networks.
178
Trustpower noted that
service providers with scale, particularly in fixed-line markets, are likely to be
interested in thick MVNO arrangements.
4.71 We discuss the emergence of wholesale competition between the MNOs in the
following section, where we note that a number of MNOs have expressed a
willingness to continue to develop commercial arrangements to provide MVNOs
with greater flexibility for differentiation and innovation. However, as noted by
RDC, thicker MVNO models will involve greater investment by the MVNO partner.
Emerging competition at the wholesale level
4.72 Until recently, competition between the MNOs to supply wholesale mobile services
to MVNOs appears to have been limited. The MVNOs that emerged in New Zealand
prior to 2015 were hosted by either Vodafone or Spark, and market evidence
indicates that commercial arrangements may have been a factor in limiting the
ability of the MVNOs to expand in the retail market. As noted in Chapter 3, the
175
RDC, “MVNO landscape: Global perspectives and New Zealand Applications”, (24 April 2019), p 14.
176
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 46; Vodafone submission on the
Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 17.
177
RDC, “MVNO landscape: Global perspectives and New Zealand Applications”, (24 April 2019), p 14.
178
Trustpower submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 5-6; Vocus cross-submission
on Preliminary Findings paper, (19 July 2019), para 22 and 25.
78
share of the retail mobile market supplied by MVNOs is around 1%, which is
considerably lower than in comparable countries.
179
4.73 Evidence collected during the study indicates that, until recently MNOs have shown
little interest in hosting MVNOs, with MVNO negotiations often being difficult and
protracted.
4.74 Trustpower has previously submitted that competitive tension at the wholesale
level in New Zealand is likely to be low, due to the third MNO being a relatively late
entrant with more limited coverage than the other MNOs.
180
2degrees has also
submitted that it had previously been limited in its ability to offer competitive
MVNO services:
181
When pricing MVNOs, 2degrees offers a national service, including coverage in areas
where it purchases national roaming services. In the past, the blended rates it offers
on voice, SMS and data would have been higher due to the costs and risks
associated with national roaming, but these have improved over the last two years
as the reliance on national roaming has reduced. Now, in 2018, national roaming
accounts for a very small amount of network traffic.
4.75 2degrees also argued that in the past, two MNOs with broadly similar market
shares had little incentive to support MVNOs, “but the presence of a growth-
oriented third network will change behaviour”.
182
2degrees pointed to similar
trends in overseas markets, where a third MNO pursues growth using MVNOs,
prompting a competitive response from incumbents.
4.76 There is some evidence to suggest that competitive conditions at the wholesale
level have recently been improving, along the lines suggested by 2degrees.
The Warehouse Mobile launched mobile services in late 2015, based on
2degrees network.
Spark submitted that it has improved the commercial terms it has been
offering for MVNO services.
183
179
For example, in its final report on its Communications Sector Market Study, the ACCC reported the market
share of MVNOs as being greater than 10%. See ACCC, “Communications Sector Market Study”,
(April 2018), Figure 4.2.
180
Trustpower, “Promoting a vibrant mobile market in New Zealand”, (3 November 2015), p 12.
181
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 17.
182
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 18.
183
Spark submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), para 113.
79
Trustpower received competing MVNO offers from 2degrees and Spark in
2018
184
In November 2018, Trustpower announced it had signed an MVNO
agreement with Spark, enabling Trustpower to start offering mobile and
wireless broadband services. Trustpower said it had nearly 400,000
customers in total across all its services, including 91,000 fixed-line
telecommunications customers.
185
Kogan Mobile, who supply mobile services in Australia, has recently
launched mobile services in New Zealand, based on its wholesale
agreement with Vodafone.
186
MyRepublic has also announced that it intends to enter as an MVNO in
Australia and New Zealand, following its entry into the Singapore
market.
187
4.77 Although it did not secure Trustpower’s MVNO business, 2degrees is likely to
continue to compete for MVNO opportunities as:
it has invested in a Mobile Virtual Network Enabler (MVNE) platform that
supports independent and differentiated MVNO models;
it can now offer comparable levels of coverage as the other MNOs; and
having incurred the fixed costs of building its network, it can improve scale
and reduce unit costs through increased wholesale activities.
4.78 Several parties have questioned whether competitive conditions at the wholesale
level have improved in recent years. For example, Trustpower submitted that while
its preference is for commercial arrangements, it is not confident that wholesale
competition has developed to provide sufficient incentives for MNOs to negotiate.
Trustpower submitted that the recent interest shown by MNOs in hosting MVNOs
is likely to be a result of this study.
188
4.79 Nova acknowledged that 2degrees is likely to compete for MVNO opportunities,
given its investment in an MVNE platform, although Nova has not yet seen any
184
2degrees submission on the issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 16.
185
Based on its 30 September 2018 results. Also
https://www.nzherald.co.nz/business/news/article.cfm?c_id=3&objectid=12163254, 20 November 2018.
186
See https://www.koganmobile.co.nz/.
187
Communications Day, “MyRepublic plans ANZ MVNO launch within a year”, (26 June 2018), and
Commerce Commission correspondence with Kogan Mobile and MyRepublic.
188
Trustpower submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 7.
80
actual evidence that 2degrees has prompted a competitive response from Spark or
Vodafone.
189
Sky questioned why the wholesale market for mobile services in
New Zealand has not yet developed as in other countries,
190
while InternetNZ also
submitted that New Zealand’s low MVNO share is out of step with other OECD
countries.
191
4.80 According to Vocus, any finding that 2degrees has increased competition at the
wholesale level is optimistic and speculative.
192
Vocus submitted that it is prepared
to be proven wrong, and it intends to issue a request for proposal (RFP) which will
give all three MNOs an equal opportunity to bid for its MVNO business.
193
4.81 2degrees has noted that it continues to be in discussion with several potential
MVNOs.
194
2degrees said that it will continue to pursue MVNO wholesale
agreements as it has invested in its own MVNE platform and has an incentive to
recover the cost of that investment.
195
4.82 2degrees also disputed other submissions that competition for MVNOs is only
emerging as a result of this study. 2degrees submitted that it had invested in its
MVNE platform prior to the commencement of this study,
196
and that it continues
to be interested in engaging in genuine commercial discussions with existing and
potential MVNOs.
4.83 For MNOs, wholesale agreements must be commercially viable. In providing
wholesale MVNO access, the MNO will risk cannibalising some of its retail market
share to the MVNO, particularly if the MNO has established sub-brands which may
be vulnerable to the MVNO.
4.84 The MNO will need to balance this risk of cannibalisation against the risk that the
MVNO will secure a wholesale agreement with a rival MNO, enabling it to compete
at the retail level in which case the MNO would then still risk losing those
customers. This risk has increased with the presence of three established mobile
networks.
4.85 For an MVNO, the commercial terms of a wholesale agreement, and in particular
the gross margin or discount off retail prices that the MVNO receives, should reflect
189
Nova submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 7(b).
190
Sky submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 20.
191
InternetNZ submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 16.
192
Vocus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 13.
193
Vocus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 17.
194
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 2.
195
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 17, 18.
196
2degress cross-submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (July 2019), p 8.
81
the functions carried out by the MVNO. As shown in Table 7, the typical gross
margins will vary, depending on the type of MVNO operating model.
4.86 We appreciate that throughout this study, a range of views have been submitted to
us on the state of the wholesale market for mobile services in New Zealand. A
number of parties have referred to New Zealand’s low MVNO market share, and
the difficulties of negotiating wholesale access, as evidence of a lack of competition
or market failure. However, in our view, market failure would need to be
demonstrated not solely on the basis of a single, narrow indicator such as MVNO
market share, but in terms of the broader market in which mobile services are
supplied to consumers. Ultimately, our concern is the long-term benefit of end
users. As discussed in Chapter 3, the performance of the mobile market has
generally improved in terms of delivering competitive outcomes to consumers
through lower prices, increasing quality, and a greater choice of services.
4.87 As noted above, competitive conditions at the wholesale level have also been
improving, in particular as a result of 2degrees completing its own national network
and reducing its reliance on Vodafone. 2degrees noted that MVNOs represent an
important source of revenue and an opportunity to grow market share, increase
utilisation of its network, and gain economies of scale. This provides 2degrees with
an incentive to continue to pursue wholesale opportunities. We have seen
evidence of this, with 2degrees investing in the development of wholesale
arrangements through its MVNE platform to support differentiated wholesale
services. 2degrees has been seeking wholesale opportunities with existing and
potential MVNOs for a number of years prior to this study.
197
4.88 During this study, we have reviewed a considerable amount of information on the
development of commercial MVNO arrangements in New Zealand. This includes
commercial agreements and supporting information. For example, one MVNO
commissioned independent advice on what reasonable commercial terms
(including retail-minus discounts) would look like. The discounts contained in the
commercial agreements that we have reviewed are broadly in line with that advice,
and with the ranges provided by RDC as summarised in Table 7.
4.89 While recent activity in the market indicates competitive conditions for MVNOs are
improving, there are barriers to switching between MNOs that may impact the
willingness of MVNOs to change their host network. One barrier is the need for an
MVNO to have its customers switch out SIM cards for their service to continue on
197
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 2.
82
another host network. The introduction and support of eSIMs by MNOs has the
potential to reduce this barrier significantly over time.
198
4.90 We note that MVNOs in other countries have emerged in a range of circumstances.
In some countries, MVNO access has been introduced via conditions on the award
of spectrum or as conditions imposed on mergers.
199
In a small number of cases,
MVNO access is directly regulated. In countries such as the UK and Australia, there
is no MVNO regulation, with MVNOs emerging as a result of commercial
negotiations.
4.91 We agree with NERA’s submission (on behalf of Spark) that access regulation of
markets with multiple competing networks is not common, and that to do so would
require compelling evidence of a competition problem or market failure.
200
NERA
also note that a lack of MVNOs may simply indicate there are not many profitable
niches for MVNOs to reach that are not already served by MNOs.
201
4.92 Wholesale competition between the MNOs has recently strengthened and is likely
to be sustained because the underlying structural conditions now exist to support
it. However, as noted earlier in this chapter, this may be influenced by the future
allocation of spectrum. In this regard, we note that the increased capacity available
on 5G networks may further stimulate wholesale activity.
4.93 As a result, there is potential for further MVNO entry and expansion, as long as the
terms of MVNO access are competitive and the MVNO is able to add value to the
retail market. Competition, supported by spectrum allocation, should deliver this.
198
We discuss eSIMs further in Chapter 6 below.
199
See for example, the Hutchison 3G Austria/Orange Austria merger in 2012 (referred to in para 4.64
above). In the US, in its recent decision on the T-Mobile/Sprint merger, the Department of Justice has
proposed a requirement to offer MVNO access to a third party (Dish). See Department of Justice,
“Proposed Final Judgment”, (26 July 2019), p 19.
200
NERA submission on behalf of Spark, “Competitive effects of MVNO’s and assessment of regulated MVNO
access”, (26 October 2018), para 3.
201
NERA submission on behalf of Spark, “Competitive effects of MVNO’s and assessment of regulated MVNO
access”, (26 October 2018), at para 5a.
83
4.94 Although we remain of the view that there is no need to intervene to regulate
MVNO access at this stage, we intend to monitor the development of MVNOs,
including ongoing monitoring of MVNO market shares and the impact that
MVNO-based entry has in the retail market. We also intend to undertake periodic
reviews of commercial MVNO arrangements. Reviewing commercial contracts will
provide us with greater ongoing visibility of the terms being offered to MVNOs,
202
and how the commercial terms compare to key price and non-price dimensions of
MVNO access. The competition that is developing at the wholesale level for MVNO
services would be expected to encompass multiple dimensions of MVNO contract
terms, including price and non-price terms. While the range of MVNO operating
models vary considerably, some of the key dimensions include the following:
pricing and margin protection;
branding and marketing;
devices and SIMs;
migration to other MVNO models;
service equivalence;
operations; and
contract termination.
4.95 Several parties submitted that as part of such monitoring, we should establish
targets for MVNO market shares, and that these could trigger an investigation into
whether to regulate MVNO access.
203
We do not agree with setting such formal
targets, as this would hinge any decision to commence a Schedule 3 investigation
on a narrow metric which may not adequately reflect any market failure. As noted
earlier, we have examined the performance of the downstream retail market by
considering a broad range of competition indicators.
4.96 We also note submissions from a number of parties that we should publish
benchmarks for a wholesale price for MVNO access, and a reference contract, in
202
During 2017, we similarly undertook a review of commercial roaming arrangements. See Commerce
Commission, “Summary of findings of investigation of the national roaming agreement between Vodafone
and 2Degrees”, (October 2017).
203
Vocus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 28; Nova submission on the
Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 10.
84
order to provide guidance to MVNOs in their negotiations with MNOs.
204
In this
regard, we refer to the gross discounts summarised in Table 7, which provides an
indication of the gross margins expected for the different forms of MVNOs. As
discussed earlier, these margins are based on RDC’s experience with MVNOs in
other markets, and are broadly consistent with other evidence we have reviewed
during this study. We do not agree with suggestions that we publish a reference
contract. Rather we think it preferable that contracts are negotiated to best suit
parties needs in the context of a competitive wholesale market.
4.97 The competition that has been emerging at the wholesale level has enabled a
number of prospective MVNOs to secure wholesale mobile access agreements with
the MNOs. Such wholesale agreements should enable further entry into the retail
mobile market, as long as MVNOs are able to offer retail services or bundles of
services that are attractive to end users.
Findings on MVNOs
F10
Until recently, wholesale competition between MNOs to host MVNOs has
been limited. MVNOs currently serve just over 1% of the retail mobile market,
although there is some evidence that increased wholesale activity by 2degrees
has prompted a response from Spark and Vodafone in offering MVNO access.
New commercial MVNO agreements have been signed during the past 18
months, such as those between Trustpower and Spark, and Kogan Mobile and
Vodafone.
F11
With three national mobile networks, sufficient competitive conditions at the
wholesale level exist and we expect MVNOs should emerge if they are
commercially viable. The commercial viability of an MVNO will in part depend
on the terms agreed with the host MNO. Based on the evidence that we have
seen and the entry expected (as noted in F10), competition at the wholesale
level has improved. However, spectrum allocation decisions will be critical to
support this competition.
F12
In light of this, we do not consider MVNO access regulation to be appropriate
at this time. There would need to be greater evidence of market failure in
respect of outcomes delivered to mobile consumers to justify wholesale access
regulation. We intend to monitor the development of MVNOs, including the
commercial terms being offered by the MNOs.
204
Vocus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 33-37; Nova submission on the
Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 10; Chorus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper,
(28 June 2019), para 26.
85
Consumer engagement and experience with mobile services
Introduction
4.98 Markets will best deliver benefits to New Zealanders when both the demand
(consumer) side of the market and the supply (provider) side of the market are
working well. Where active and well-informed consumers switch to those providers
who best meet their needs, suppliers are incentivised to innovate and efficiently
meet those needs. Active customers who are prepared to switch will also make it
easier for new suppliers to enter and expand by lowering customer acquisition
costs.
4.99 This section sets out our consideration of:
how effectively mobile consumers are able to engage in the mobile
market, following the three As (Access, Assess, and Act) approach to
evaluating the state of consumer engagement within the mobile
market;
205
whether mobile consumers exhibit behavioural biases which may influence
competition between existing suppliers as well as the prospect for
potential suppliers to enter the mobile market; and
potential remedies and actions that could be taken to promote consumer
engagement in the mobile market.
4.100 We then summarise our views on consumer engagement in the mobile market.
How easily can consumers access the information they need?
4.101 For consumers to be able to engage effectively in the mobile market and make
informed purchasing decisions, they need to have the right information available to
them. Consumers need to access information on both the key features of
competing offers and their own mobile usage in order to compare these offers and
to select which offer will best meet their needs.
4.102 Consumers can freely access plan information on mobile provider websites (and
comparison websites).
206
Consumers can also gain (often incomplete) plan
information through advertising and word-of-mouth.
205
Office of Fair Trading, “What does Behavioural Economics mean for Competition Policy?”, (March 2010),
p 10-17.
206
As discussed below, the utility of price comparison websites will depend on how the information is
presented.
86
4.103 According to Consumer NZ’s survey of mobile consumers, most consumers appear
to find it easy to access their mobile usage information, as shown in Figure 14.
4.104 The same survey also showed the ways in which consumers access their usage
information, with 58% of consumers accessing their usage via a mobile app, 18% via
their provider’s website, and 16% via their monthly bill (although we note that this
usage information is often limited to a short time period eg, one month). In their
submissions throughout this study, the MNOs also noted that consumers can
access their usage information on their mobile provider’s app or website.
Figure 14 Ease of accessing mobile usage information
4.105 Along with plan information and their usage trends, consumers could benefit from
information on mobile performance ie, the quality of the mobile service they are
currently receiving or could possibly receive from another provider. While all three
MNOs have coverage maps on their websites there is no shared map for consumers
that compares coverage between the three MNOs.
4.106 In addition, even when there is nominal coverage there may be ‘holes’ in this
coverage caused by a range of factors eg, signal degradation caused by buildings
and/or topography, or network base stations being at or nearing capacity.
207
How easily can consumers assess the information they have?
4.107 Even if consumers have access to usage and performance information, they also
need to be able to assess their options ie, the plans available in the market and
service quality against their mobile service needs. This assessment is complicated in
that consumers need to anticipate what their future usage will be.
4.108 The presence of complex choices and/or of non-transparent add-on costs may
make plan comparisons more difficult. This can lead to consumer confusion,
deterring consumers from actively comparing retail plans. Even where consumers
do compare plans, they may end up making poor choices.
207
See, for example, the earlier discussion of 3G and 4G availability in the context of quality of mobile service
in Chapter 3.
87
4.109 As an example, where prices are advertised on a non-standardised basis, the ability
of consumers to correctly identify the cheapest option will be affected. In this
regard, we note that Skinny offers bundles of mobile minutes, texts, and mobile
data which renew every 28 days. Other mobile providers offer bundles of minutes,
texts, and data on a monthly basis. In order to make a valid comparison, consumers
would have to adjust the prices and allowances of the Skinny offer to a monthly
equivalent. For example, Skinny’s $77 plan with unlimited minutes and texts, and
‘unlimited’ data (with speeds throttled once a 40GB threshold is reached) is
equivalent to $83.42 per month.
4.110 We also note that mobile providers typically offer a range of add-on options which
allow consumers to purchase additional minutes or data. Where a consumer is not
aware of these additional charges, their ability to select the plan best suited to their
needs will be diminished.
4.111 Such confusion may deter consumers from comparing retail plans. As shown in
Figure 15, most consumers do not compare mobile plans frequently.
Figure 15 Frequency of comparing plans
4.112 2degrees submitted that this was not cause for concern as customers that are
happy tend not to invest time and effort into reviewing other plans.
2degrees noted
that according to Consumer NZ’s survey of mobile consumers, 70% of consumers
are satisfied with their current mobile service provider.
208
4.113 Nevertheless, consumers may be able to get a better deal if they did compare
available options. If many consumers ‘never’ or ‘rarely’ compare plans due to the
difficulty of the process, this would be a significant concern. As shown in Figure 16
this does not appear to be the case, as over half of respondents find it easy to
compare plans.
208
2degrees submission on the Preliminary Findings paper (28 June 2019), p 12. We note that Consumer NZ
found that 70% of consumers who have not switched within the last 12 months were satisfied with their
service.
88
Figure 16 Ease of comparing providers and plans
4.114 It is worth noting that some consumer segments find it relatively more difficult to
compare plans. For example, 32% of consumers aged 65 or older in the Consumer
NZ survey found it ‘difficult’ to compare mobile providers and plans.
209
It may also
be the case that although they generally perceive it to be easy to compare retail
plans, consumers may not actually end up on the plan that is best suited to their
needs.
4.115 The business segment covers a range of customers, with differing abilities and
attitudes to reviewing competing mobile plans. Smaller enterprises may face similar
search costs and challenges as residential customers when assessing retail offers.
Larger corporate customers with higher level of spend on mobile services (often
within a whole of business contract) or with more specific requirements are more
likely to be better served due to the value of their business. Such customers will
often have a procurement team to manage competitive tenders and contracts.
4.116 An important issue for consumers being able to make informed purchasing
decisions is whether accurate and clear information is available. We have
investigated misleading claims from mobile providers in the past. These have
included:
misleading consumers over 2G network closures;
210
and
the clarity and visibility of contract terms and charges for SMS/multimedia
media services (MMS)/data when consumers send messages or exceed
their data bundle allowances.
4.117 These are indicative of the issues consumers can face when trying to assess which
offers in the market may best meet their needs.
Bundling
4.118 While bundles may provide consumers with benefits in the form of discounts and
convenience (one bill, one point of contact), the presence of bundles adds another
209
Consumer NZ, Telco Consumer Survey 2018.
210
Commerce Commission media release, “Four telcos warned by Commission”, (14 Aug 2017).
89
factor the consumer must consider when comparing plans. This can make it more
difficult for consumers to assess different retail offers.
4.119 Bundling of services can also increase customer stickiness, for example:
Trustpower has reported that churn rates for bundled services (electricity,
gas and broadband) are materially lower than for standalone energy
services;
211
and
in our 2018 decision on the proposed merger between Sky and Vodafone,
we noted evidence indicating that bundling reduces customer churn and
increases customer acquisition costs.
212
4.120 As discussed earlier, uptake of bundles that include mobile services is currently low
among residential consumers. Consumer NZ found that 73% of respondents in its
2018 survey do not bundle their mobile service with other services, and Analysys
Mason’s Connected Consumer Survey also found that when choosing a mobile plan,
the ability to bundle mobile connectivity with other services was ranked relatively
low by respondents.
213
Of consumers who do bundle their mobile service, most
bundle it together with fixed-line broadband and/or streaming services.
4.121 The prevalence of business consumers buying mobile services as part of a wider
bundle is likely to be higher than residential customers due to the importance of
whole of business connectivity. For example, in our 2015 business mobile market
study, 78% of businesses said that bundled solutions are important.
214
As noted in
the preceding paragraph, Analysys Mason has found that bundling is ranked
relatively low by individual consumers.
4.122 Currently in New Zealand there do not appear to be any bundles of mobile services
with products for which there are no good alternatives. However, the Commission
will continue to monitor the development of bundles.
211
Trustpower, “Investor Briefing 2018 half Year Results”, (8 November 2018), slide 7.
212
Commerce Commission, “Vodafone Europe B.V. and Sky Network Television Limited [2017] NZCC 1 Sky
Network Television Limited and Vodafone New Zealand Limited [2017] NZCC 2”, (22 February 2018),
para X26, 182 to 185.
213
Consumer NZ, Telco Consumer Survey 2018; Analysys Mason, “Connected Consumer Survey 2018: mobile
customer satisfaction in Australia and New Zealand”, slide 11.
214
UMR, “Competition for Business Customers in the Mobile industry: A Report for the Commerce
Commission”, (December 2015), p 28.
90
4.123 We will also continue monitoring the uptake of bundles that include mobile
services to assess whether firms may be using bundles strategically to raise barriers
to entry and to limit the market available to competitors.
How easy is it for consumers to act?
4.124 The level of switching observed in a market may be indicative of the ability of
consumers to act and take advantage of competing offers. Various types of costs
consumers incur can impede switching.
215
4.125 However, it is important to understand what underpins the level of switching
including the reasons for switching or not switching, and any barriers to switching
and the implications for consumers. For example:
a high level of switching may result in poorer consumer outcomes if
consumers end up on plans that make them worse off. For example,
research in the UK has found that 17% of consumers switching electricity
suppliers ended up worse off;
216
and
a low level of switching may reflect a high level of satisfaction among
consumers with their current supplier, with suppliers competing to retain
their customers.
217
4.126 Over the past four years the number of mobile subscribers who have ported (kept)
their number when switching between suppliers has stayed constant at around 5%
per annum.
218
The Consumer NZ 2018 survey indicates a slightly higher rate of
switching (9% in the past 12 months) which could be in part explained by
customers relinquishing their number when they switch.
219
This is slightly lower
than numbers for Australia at 10% and the average for 28 European countries at
13%.
220
4.127 In our 2015 business mobile market study we found that 14% of businesses had
changed mobile provider within the previous two years, and that this was lower
215
For example, transaction costs, compatibility costs, learning costs, contractual costs or psychological costs,
see Office of Fair Trading (UK) OFT655, “Switching Costs Economics Discussion Paper 5: Part One Economic
models and policy implications”, (April 2003), Ch 2.
216
Wilson, C., and Waddams Price, C., “Do Consumers Switch to the Best Supplier?”, (10 March 2010).
217
This may be by way of suppliers’ drip-feeding incremental improvements to their customers.
218
Porting numbers are from the New Zealand Telecommunications Forum (TCF) Number Portability
Statistics, overall subscriber numbers are from our Annual Monitoring Questionnaire.
219
Consumer NZ, Telco Consumer Survey 2018.
220
ACCC, “Communications Sector Market Study Final Report”, (April 2018), p 120; European Commission,
“Consumer Markets Scoreboard 2018 Edition”, (2018), Fig 25.
91
than the percentage of businesses that had switched power company (26%) but
higher than the percentage that had switched banks (5%).
221
4.128 Both 2degrees and Spark submitted that, in their experience, switching levels are
higher than the statistics above, as the statistics above exclude ‘internal switches’
where a customer changes plans but not their provider.
222
While we acknowledge
that internal switching between plans offered by the same supplier may indicate
that consumers are more active, we consider that switching between suppliers is
more relevant to competition.
4.129 While the switching statistics show that some consumers are moving, over half of
residential consumers have not switched provider in the last five years (see Figure
17).
Figure 17 Time with current provider
4.130 There is no fixed proportion of the market that should be expected to switch.
Consumers not switching provider is not necessarily a concern if those consumers
do not face significant barriers to switching.
4.131 Figure 18 shows that 19% of consumers think that it is difficult to switch.
Figure 18 Perceived ease of switching provider
221
UMR Research, “Competition for Business Customers in the Mobile Industry: A Report for the Commerce
Commission”, (December 2015), p 91, 96.
222
2degrees submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 13; Spark submission on the
Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 59, 60.
92
4.132 A low level of switching could also reflect that consumers are generally satisfied
with their current provider. As shown in Figure 19, 70% of consumers who have not
switched in the past 12 months stayed with their current provider because they are
satisfied with the service they are receiving.
Figure 19 Main reason for staying with provider
4.133 Spark agreed with this hypothesis, submitting that year-on-year increases in value,
quality and other benefits mean that customers are content to remain with their
current supplier.
223
This view was supported by 2degrees during the
cross-submission process.
224
4.134 2degrees also noted in its cross-submission that customers can often meet their
needs by switching between plans rather than mobile providers.
225
4.135 Although satisfaction with current provider is the most common reason given for
not switching, a number of the other reasons given by mobile consumers for
remaining with their current provider relate to barriers to switching. These include
a lack of confidence of getting a better deal, perceptions around the effort involved
in changing providers, and the presence of fixed contracts.
223
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 2.
224
2degrees cross-submission on Preliminary Findings paper, (19 July 2019), p 9.
225
2degrees cross-submission on Preliminary Findings paper, (19 July 2019), p 9.
93
Switching barriers
4.136 A number of barriers to switching suppliers have been reduced in the mobile
market. This is likely to explain why most consumers consider switching between
mobile suppliers to be easy.
4.137 Most importantly, the introduction of mobile number portability has reduced
switching costs by allowing consumers to retain their numbers when they change
suppliers.
4.138 Another example relates to handset locking. As previously noted, the practice of
locking handsets increases switching costs and has led to us raising concerns over
the practice in the past.
226
4.139 We will continue to monitor the number of locked handsets and the break fees
attached to these phones. Even where break fees do not apply, the inconvenience
of having to unlock a device is likely to raise switching costs for the consumer.
4.140 There have been cases of consumers on fixed-term contracts that include a handset
continuing to pay the same price for mobile services beyond the end of their
contract.
227
As pointed out in submissions during this study, this is not a significant
issue in New Zealand as there has been a move away from fixed-term contracts
which include handsets in the residential market.
228
4.141 While the move away from fixed-term contracts for residential customers will have
made switching easier, there is likely a trade-off in that contract plans can offer
considerably better value. As seen in Australia, twelve-month contracts often offer
better value in exchange for the commitment of a contract, particularly enabling
much higher data allowances. However, we note that Telstra has recently moved
away from mobile plans with fixed-term contracts.
4.142 In the business segment, our 2015 business mobile market study found that 73% of
businesses surveyed were on fixed-term contracts.
229
Our 2018 annual monitoring
questionnaire found that 58% of business customers were on fixed-term contracts.
This suggests there may have been a move towards open term contracts, similar to
the current trend in the residential on-account segment where the market has
moved towards handset payment plans.
226
While we raised concerns in the past, we also noted that a transparent lock in period that reflects the
recovery of subsidised costs may not undermine competition.
227
Behavioural Insights Team “Applying behavioural insights to regulated markets”, (26 May 2016), p 45.
228
For example, 2degrees submission on the Issues Paper, (October 2018), p 29; Spark submission on the
Issues Paper, (26 October 2018), para 157.
229
Commerce Commission, “Summary of business mobile market segment study” (30 March 2017).
94
4.143 We note that while concerns may arise with fixed-term contracts that have
excessive terms, we are not opposed to the existence of fixed-term contracts
per se. The existence of twelve-month contracts alongside pay-monthly plans may
be positive from a consumer choice perspective.
Behavioural biases
4.144 We have examined whether consumers, when faced with competing retail offers of
mobile services, may make decisions in which they fail to select an offer that would
better meet their needs than their current offer. Such decisions may result from
‘behavioural biases’ which inhibit consumers from making better choices.
230
4.145 As discussed above, more than half of respondents to Consumer NZ’s mobile
consumer survey reported that they had been with their current provider for more
than five years. This may indicate a preference among the majority of mobile
consumers for the familiarity of their current supplier (a preference for the ‘status
quo’).
4.146 Although a reason given by most mobile consumers for not switching is that they
are satisfied with their current provider, we note that mobile consumers tend to
compare alternative offers infrequently. As a result, such consumers may be
unaware if there are other retail offers available that might better meet their
needs.
4.147 It may also be the case that a consumer’s existing supplier offers incremental
improvements in value (such as additional data for the same monthly price) in
order to retain the customer and to reduce their propensity to shop around. As
discussed earlier, both Spark and 2degrees have noted that increases in value,
quality and other benefits mean that customers are more likely to remain with
their current supplier.
231
,
232
This may reinforce a ‘status quo’ bias, even if better
offers were available elsewhere.
4.148 Even if consumers were aware of better competing offers, there is research that
indicates that consumers “value what they have more than what they might have”.
Such an aversion to losing what they currently have may result in consumers
230
Behavioural Insights Team, “Behavioural Biases in Telecommunications: A review for the Commerce
Commission”, (May 2019).
231
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 2.
232
2degrees cross-submission on Preliminary Findings paper, (19 July 2019), p 9.
95
missing out on benefits from switching, as competing suppliers would have to offer
substantial inducements to get a consumer to switch.
233
4.149 Consumers may also be overconfident in their ability to forecast their usage, for
example the number of minutes or the amount of data they will use each month.
This may be an issue where demand is changing rapidly, and the costs of incorrectly
forecasting usage are high. In this regard, the cost of purchasing additional mobile
data appear to be relatively high. For example, Vodafone’s mobile data add-ons
include $15 for 1GB, and 2degrees’ mobile data add-ons include $20 for $1GB.
234
4.150 Where a customer’s actual usage is higher than expected and results in the
customer having to purchase additional data, this can result in a monthly bill that is
significantly higher than expected (a form of ‘bill shock’).
4.151 Conversely, where customers overestimate their usage, they may end up with
unused minutes and data. Where unused allowances can be rolled over, the
customer can carry forward unused balances. However, where this persists, this
may indicate that the customer is on a more expensive plan that is necessary to
meet their usage.
4.152 Spark submitted that it is not convinced that the Commission’s analysis of
behavioural biases reflects the complexity of customer behaviour. Spark argued
that more longitudinal evidence (data over a longer period) is required to be
confident that a behavioural bias problem exists. Spark expects that further analysis
would confirm that there is no behavioural bias problem.
235
4.153 Similarly, Vodafone submitted that customers are often in the best position to
make decisions about their plans and that plan decisions can be influenced by
several factors that are entirely rational and in the consumers interest.
236
4.154 We agree that consumer decision making is complex and that there can be a wide
range of reasons for consumers staying with their provider or plan. To shed light on
whether the high number of customers choosing to remain with their mobile
supplier is cause for concern, we are currently undertaking some research into the
extent to which mobile consumers are on retail plans that do not best suit their
needs. This is discussed further below.
233
Lunn P. “Telecommunications Consumers: A Behavioural Economic Analysis”, (19 January 2012), p 10-11.
234
Operator websites accessed September 2019.
235
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 57-58.
236
Vodafone submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 7.
96
Are consumers on plans that are suited to their usage?
4.155 Although there is some evidence that mobile consumers find it easy to compare
retail plans, they only do so infrequently. Consumers may therefore be unaware if
there are other retail offers available that might better meet their needs. This is a
potentially important issue to ensure that suppliers face the correct incentives to
compete for customers. At this stage, we do not have robust evidence on whether
mobile subscribers are on plans that are well-suited to their usage.
4.156 We are currently analysing mobile bills to understand whether mobile consumers
are ‘leaving money on the table’ by remaining on plans that are more expensive
than they need to be in order to satisfy their usage. There are two situations where
a consumer may be paying too much for mobile services:
237
a consumer’s actual usage (in terms of minutes, SMS, and mobile data
used per month) is lower than the allowance they are purchasing; or
a consumer’s actual usage could be met using a cheaper plan (either with
the same operator or with a competing operator).
4.157 Consumers must anticipate their future needs to assess which plan best meets their
needs. This can be difficult for consumers,
238
although a number of plans currently
available (such as Vodafones MyFlex plan) provide consumers with flexibility to
adjust in light of their usage.
239
This has been raised as an issue in other markets
(such as electricity) where consumers have not necessarily chosen the best plan.
240
4.158 We will be looking to understand the best approaches to encourage consumers to
review their current plans and to consider switching to alternatives that may offer
better value. We are undertaking some analysis of mobile bills as part of our wider
section 9A monitoring and consumer work, outside of this study.
Potential remedies/actions
4.159 It appears that consumers can access information on mobile services, assess
alternatives, and switch relatively easily. However, consumers do not appear to
frequently compare mobile plans, and there are some features of mobile plans
which may reduce the ability of consumers to identify plans that are best suited to
237
We note that consumers may also be willing to pay more for improved service.
238
Dr P Xavier, “Behavioural Economics and Customer Complaints in Communications Markets”, (May 2011),
Ch 5.
239
An example in the case of fixed broadband services is Spark’s ‘Unplan’ offers.
240
Wilson, Chris M. and Price, Catherine Waddams, Do Consumers Switch to the Best Supplier?”, (10 March
2010). This found that 17% of consumers in the UK electricity market reduced their surplus (were worse
off) by switching.
97
their usage. We also note that a large proportion of mobile consumers have
remained with their current supplier for five years or more.
4.160 The passage of the Telecommunications (New Regulatory Framework) Amendment
Act 2018 introduced several new consumer provisions aimed at improving retail
service quality (RSQ) through increased information and added consumer
protections. These provisions apply to both fixed-line and mobile
telecommunications.
4.161 Both 2degrees and Vodafone expressed concern in their submissions over possible
regulatory action in this area:
2degrees commented that it is keen to ensure that the Commission’s
responses are proportionate to any problem/s that are identified. It also
outlined that it would be concerned if an expensive and complex
consumer engagement mechanism were to be introduced;
241
and
Vodafone noted that any intervention that limits consumer choice risks
creating worse outcomes for New Zealanders.
242
4.162 We agree that any regulatory action or intervention needs to be proportionate and
take account of the potential costs. At this stage we are not advocating regulatory
action in relation to consumer engagement in the mobile market. However, mobile
consumers will continue to be considered as part of our wider consumer and RSQ
work. This will help ensure that any future interventions are proportionate.
4.163 Our analysis of mobile bills is being conducted separately from this mobile market
study and the results of this analysis will inform our ongoing monitoring and
oversight of the mobile market as well as wider consumer and RSQ activities.
4.164 There have been recent legislative changes in Australia to introduce a Consumer
Data Right (CDR), which will first apply to banking, followed by energy and then
possibly telecommunications.
243
MBIE is considering the role that CDR initiatives
could play in the New Zealand commercial and consumer environment. The CDR is
essentially a data portability right and has the potential to enable greater levels of
transparency and encourage competition between providers.
241
2degress submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 13-14.
242
Vodafone submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 8.
243
ACCC website, Consumer Data Right, (28 March 2019), https://www.accc.gov.au/focus-areas/consumer-
data-right-cdr-0.
98
4.165 Establishing a CDR that achieves the desired outcomes is not easy.
244
As noted
earlier, it appears that mobile consumers are already able to access information
about their usage of mobile services. Hence, we are proposing to continue to
monitor developments in Australia and other markets rather than recommending
the introduction of such a measure in New Zealand.
4.166 Price comparison websites can facilitate the comparison of different mobile service
plans and lower search costs for consumers. However, there may be concerns over
the transparency and independence of these websites and the accuracy of the
information they present.
245
As price comparison websites cover both mobile and
fixed telecommunications services, we will evaluate them further, outside of this
study, as part of our wider consumer work.
244
Behavioural Insights Team, “Behavioural Biases in Telecommunications: A review for the Commerce
Commission”, (May 2019).
245
Ofcom runs an accreditation scheme for price comparison websites to ensure that comparisons of services
are “accessible, accurate, transparent and comprehensive.” See https://www.ofcom.org.uk/consultations-
and-statements/category-2/price-calculator-accreditation.
99
Findings on consumer engagement
F13
Most consumers can easily access their mobile usage information, but
information on mobile performance (speeds, actual quality of coverage etc) is
harder to access.
F14
Most consumers find it easy to compare available plans, but report that they
only do so infrequently.
F15
Our evidence shows that the process for residential consumers to switch
between mobile suppliers is relatively easy, given that:
a) mobile number portability is available;
b) there are low numbers of locked handsets; and
c) long-term contracts for residential consumers are not prominent.
Bundling of mobile and fixed-line services, which can increase customer
stickiness, does not appear to be widespread in the residential market.
F16
While residential consumers report being able to easily access usage
information and compare plans, and that the process of switching appears to
be relatively easy, a significant proportion of consumers have not compared
plans in the last 12 months and have remained with their current supplier for
more than five years. This suggests that there is a degree of consumer inertia,
and we have commenced a review of mobile bills to shed light on whether this
is cause for concern.
F17
Switching in the business market appears to be more complex and more
infrequent than residential mobile services. Businesses typically purchase
mobile and fixed services as a package, often through fixed-term contracts,
with brand reputation being an important driver. Larger business customers
are more sophisticated buyers, generally have more access to specialist advice
and support, and are more likely to have dedicated procurement resources.
100
Chapter 5 State of competition in the mobile market
Purpose and structure of this chapter
Purpose
5.1 In this chapter, we set out our views on the state of competition in the mobile
market. This draws on our overview of the mobile market in Chapter 3 and on our
assessment of the key issues discussed in Chapter 4.
Structure
5.2 We first discuss how competition between the existing mobile suppliers has
evolved since the entry of the third MNO. We then consider the conditions for
further expansion by existing suppliers and for entry of new suppliers. We conclude
with our views on whether consumers have been able to take advantage of
competition between suppliers of mobile services.
Our view on the state of competition in the mobile market
Existing competition
5.3 Competition in the New Zealand mobile market has become more established with
the emergence of the third MNO.
246
The entry of 2degrees, and the completion of
its own national network in recent years, has resulted in mobile consumers now
having the choice of three independent network-based competitors, each offering
similar levels of population and geographic coverage.
5.4 We have previously noted that the entry of 2degrees had a significant impact in
terms of improving consumer choice and competitive offerings. When 2degrees
first entered in 2009, it initially offered prepaid mobile services,
247
with prices that
were significantly lower than those offered by Vodafone and Telecom at the
time.
248
246
For a discussion of established competition, see Yarrow, G., “Report on the impact of maintaining price
regulation”, (January 2008).
247
2degrees started offering on account mobile services in 2010.
248
Commerce Commission, “New Zealand Retail Prices for Fixed Line and Mobile Services: A Benchmarking
Comparison”, (November 2010), p 23.
101
5.5 Both Vodafone and Spark have responded to the entry and expansion of 2degrees.
For example:
in early 2012, Spark launched its Skinny brand offering prepaid mobile
bundles, initially targeting the youth end of the market before refocusing
as a budget brand in 2013;
249
in 2014, we noted that competition had been more intense in the low to
medium use and prepaid segments of the mobile market, as evidenced by
a reduction in prices in these segments compared to the OECD average;
250
and
in 2016, Vodafone introduced its MyFlex prepaid plan, providing
customers with the flexibility to adjust the number of minutes, texts, and
data in their prepaid bundles.
5.6 Such competition has continued and has extended into the higher value segments
of the retail market. For example, all three MNOs now offer bundles of unlimited
minutes, SMS and unlimited data (although all of these plans have data
thresholds, beyond which the quality of the service is degraded). Several recent
market developments have improved value for higher usage mobile consumers in
New Zealand.
In April 2019, 2degrees introduced a shared ‘unlimited’ plan, at $85 per
month with a data threshold of 40GB beyond which speeds are reduced.
The price per subscriber drops as additional subscribers are added. Up to
four people can subscribe to the plan, at which point each subscriber gets
40GB for $40 per month. In addition, 2degrees offered a short-term
promotion in June 2019, offering a 50% discount on most of its pay-
monthly prices for three months.
In May 2019, Skinny added a 40GB plan for $77, renewing every four
weeks. When adjusted to a monthly basis, the Skinny plan offers 43GB for
$83.
As Spark noted in its submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, it
recently increased the threshold at which speeds are throttled on its
unlimited mobile plans, from 22GB to 40GB.
251
According to Spark, there
249
Commerce Commission, “Annual Telecommunications Monitoring Report 2014”, (June 2015), p 25.
250
Commerce Commission, “International Price Comparison for Retail Mobile Telecommunications Services
2013”, (March 2014), p 17.
251
Spark submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 9c.
102
has been a significant shift towards such plans in the New Zealand
market.
252
Vodafone has also recently increased the threshold on its unlimited
plans, from 22GB to 40GB.
In September 2019, Kogan Mobile commenced offering prepaid mobile
plans with unlimited calls and SMS, and up to 32GB per month. Subscribers
can pay in advance for 30 days, 90 days, or 365 days.
5.7 As shown earlier in Figure 3, the overall market shares of the three MNOs have
been quite stable in recent years. Over the five years to 2018, Spark’s share of
mobile subscribers increased from 34% to 38%, largely as a result of Skinny’s
increase in the prepaid segment. Vodafone’s share has dropped from 44% to 41%,
with declines in the residential segment and gains in the business segment.
5.8 2degrees’ overall market share has been flat in recent years, and it has a relatively
high proportion of prepaid customers, resulting in a lower ARPU. However, it has
been continuing to expand in the higher value residential on-account segment,
albeit at a growth rate that appears to be slowing.
5.9 As discussed in Chapter 3, prices of mobile services in New Zealand have been
falling, as evidenced by ARPU and usage trends. The volume of mobile voice
minutes and mobile data used by each mobile subscriber has continued to increase,
although average mobile data usage in New Zealand remains relatively low by
international standards. This may be due to a number of factors, including pricing
of higher usage bundles and the availability and quality of fixed networks in
New Zealand.
5.10 A number of submissions throughout this study have argued that the mobile
market in New Zealand is competitive and has been performing well.
253
Other
submitters put forward a different view, that competition is not effective at the
retail (and wholesale) level, and that 2degrees had struggled to compete as a result
of its limited network coverage and its reliance on roaming.
254
252
Spark cross-submission on Preliminary Findings paper, (19 July 2019), para 10.
253
Spark submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 2; NERA, “Competition in the New Zealand
Mobile Market”, (26 October 2018), para 29, 32, 34; 2degrees submission on the Issues paper,
(26 October 2018), p 7; Vodafone submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 3. Also see
submissions from these parties on the Preliminary Findings paper.
254
Trustpower submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), para 3.1.1; Vocus submission on the Issues
paper, (26 October 2018), para 11; WISPA NZ submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 2. Also,
see submissions on the Preliminary Findings paper.
103
5.11 We note that as it was deploying and expanding its own network, 2degrees’
reliance on roaming may have constrained its ability to independently compete in
some segments. 2degrees entered by building its own mobile network in the main
centres (initially covering 47% of New Zealand’s population with its own network)
and relying on roaming on Vodafone’s mobile network in order to be able to offer
national coverage.
5.12 2degrees has since extended its own network coverage to reach levels similar to
the other MNOs. Figure 20 summarises the latest information available from our
2018 annual monitoring questionnaire, showing 3G and 4G coverage of each MNO.
Figure 20 Total national 3G and 4G coverage (2018)
5.13 As 2degrees invested in expanding its own network coverage, its reliance on
roaming on Vodafone’s network has diminished. 2degrees submitted that it relies
on roaming for less than 1.5% of its traffic.
255
This is consistent with the responses
to our annual monitoring questionnaire.
5.14 There is some evidence that in the past, 2degrees’ smaller network footprint may
have created reputational challenges in serving some segments of the mobile
market. For example, in our 2015 mobile market study into the business segment
of the mobile market, we found a general perception among business customers
that 2degrees offered a lower service quality and less extensive coverage.
255
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 2.
104
5.15 However, we also found that those business customers who subscribed to 2degrees
were the most satisfied (93% of business customers were satisfied with their
mobile service, compared to 77% for Spark and 81% for Vodafone).
256
5.16 After 10 years in the mobile market, 2degrees has an established track record as an
MNO in New Zealand and a number of parties have acknowledged that perceptions
of 2degrees appear to be changing.
257
We also note that 2degrees is the only
telecommunications provider to appear in Colmar Brunton’s Corporate Reputation
Index in 2019, which is a measure of New Zealand’s most respected brands.
258
5.17 According to 2degrees, the completion of its network build means that the
structure of the New Zealand mobile market is set for increased retail and
wholesale competition:
259
Achieving a comparable footprint to its competitors means New Zealand now has
three truly national network operators. This creates enduring competitive tension
because 2degrees, as the newest entrant, is strongly incentivised to continue
growing to deliver a return on past investment and fund upcoming 5G
deployment.
5.18 As noted earlier, 2degrees has invested in the development of wholesale
arrangements through its MVNE platform, which allows wholesale customers to
develop their own differentiated products.
260
5.19 It therefore appears that 2degrees is well-positioned to compete in the supply of
mobile services across all customer segments.
5.20 However, as we discuss in Chapter 4, the ability of each MNO to compete going
forward will also depend on the amount and type of spectrum held by the MNOs.
Conditions for further expansion and entry
5.21 In considering the ability of existing suppliers of mobile services to expand further,
and new suppliers to enter, we have examined potential barriers to entry and
expansion which could influence competition in the New Zealand mobile market
going forward.
256
UMR Research, “Competition for Business Customers in the Mobile Industry: A Report for the Commerce
Commission”, (December 2015), p 87.
257
For example, WISPA NZ submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 2.
258
Colmar Brunton, “Corporate reputation Index 2019”, available at https://www.colmarbrunton.co.nz/wp-
content/uploads/2019/04/Colmar-Brunton-Corporate-Reputation-Report-April-2019.pdf.
259
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 1.
260
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 17.
105
5.22 For MNOs, access to adequate spectrum will be an important issue to sustain
competition and to accommodate rapidly growing demand for services supplied
over mobile networks, particularly mobile data and wireless broadband services
which require significant capacity. We note that disparities in spectrum holdings
can potentially affect downstream competition, and that this may be a particularly
important issue for consideration in the upcoming allocation of 3.5 GHz spectrum.
5.23 As discussed in Chapter 4, there does not appear to be a case for regulatory
intervention to promote a fourth MNO to enter the market. However, we consider
it appropriate to allow parties other than the existing three MNOs to participate in
future spectrum acquisition processes.
5.24 The availability of national roaming is also important for an entrant as it builds out
its own network. National roaming allowed 2degrees to offer widespread coverage
as it invested in its own network. Roaming remains a specified service in Schedule 1
of the Telecommunications Act.
5.25 For MVNO-based competitors, the availability of MVNO access on competitive
terms will influence the ability of MVNOs to enter and evolve in the retail market.
We note that there are a range of MVNO operating models, and we have assessed
information on existing and potential MVNOs in New Zealand.
5.26 Until recently, competition between the MNOs to supply wholesale mobile services
to MVNOs appears to have been subdued. Absent competition from 2degrees, the
other MNOs appear to have shown little interest to offer MVNO access, suggesting
unsatisfactory wholesale market conditions for MVNOs.
5.27 There is some evidence to suggest that competitive conditions at the wholesale
level have recently been improving, with 2degrees more aggressively pursuing
wholesale opportunities. As discussed in Chapter 4, 2degrees has invested in the
platforms and systems to support more independent and differentiated MVNO
models. This is evidenced by its efforts to attract Trustpower’s MVNO business.
Vocus recently submitted that it intends to test the wholesale market by issuing an
RFP for its MVNO business.
5.28 The other MNOs appear to have been responding. 2degrees submitted that it has
driven a ‘positive competitive dynamic’ for MVNOs, with Trustpower announcing
that it will be launching retail services following a competitive MVNO process won
by Spark.
261
We also note that Kogan Mobile has recently launched MVNO-based
mobile services.
261
2degrees submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (June 2019), p 3.
106
5.29 2degrees is likely to face ongoing incentives to attract MVNOs onto its network in
order to recover its investment in its MVNE platform, and to help it grow mobile
volumes and achieve economies of scale. Its ability to continue to do so is likely to
depend on gaining adequate spectrum in future allocations.
5.30 We therefore consider that competitive conditions are emerging that are likely to
support commercial MVNO activity where there is a market opportunity for such
services. The prospects for MVNO-based entry and expansion are also likely to
depend on whether consumers of mobile services are actively engaged and
prepared to switch between suppliers.
Consumer engagement
5.31 As competing suppliers emerge in a market, the increased range of choice and
offers can give rise to issues around the level of consumer engagement and
confidence. As we have noted, if consumers find it difficult to compare proliferating
offers and to choose the services that best meet their needs, this is likely to create
barriers to entry and expansion in the supply of mobile services.
5.32 In Chapter 4, we examined the available evidence on the ability of consumers to
compare alternative offers and to switch between service providers.
5.33 It is important for consumers of mobile services to be able to easily access
information on their usage and to compare retail prices of mobile services. It
appears that most consumers can easily get information on their monthly usage,
such as the number of minutes and texts, and the amount of data they use
(although usage history is often limited to a short time period eg, one month).
Consumers also appear to find it easy to compare retail plans, but only do so
infrequently.
5.34 Non-price features of mobile services are less visible to consumers, including
information on speeds and the extent and quality of coverage.
5.35 Switching between mobile suppliers appears to be relatively easy, given that
mobile number portability is available, there are low numbers of locked handsets,
and that long-term contracts for residential consumers are not prominent in
New Zealand. Despite this, a significant proportion of consumers have remained
with their current supplier for more than five years, suggesting a degree of
customer inertia.
5.36 A key reason why consumers state they remain with their current supplier is that
they are satisfied with their service. However, this does not generally reflect active
comparison by many consumers of alternatives and may simply reflect a status quo
bias encouraged by gradual improvements in plan content. Consumers give a
107
variety of reasons for remaining with their current supplier, including the customer
being unsure whether they could get a better deal elsewhere.
Findings on the state of competition
F18
Our view is that competition in the retail mobile market has become more
established with three independent, national network-based competitors. This
has resulted in mobile consumers benefitting from an increasingly competitive
market environment.
F19
There remain some areas where we anticipate competitive outcomes for
consumers could improve further, such as pricing for higher usage bundles of
mobile services, (although recent market developments have improved
consumer outcomes for higher usage bundles). Average mobile data usage in
New Zealand remains low by international standards, which may be due to a
number of factors, including pricing of higher usage bundles and the
availability and quality of fixed networks (including WiFi hotspots) in
New Zealand.
F20
We believe that the conditions for effective competition exist, with the three
MNOs each having a network of similar technology with similar geographic and
population coverage metrics. We consider that:
a) spectrum must be allocated with wholesale and retail competition
matters at the forefront of decisions;
b) with the pre-conditions for competition in place and the adequate
allocation of spectrum, we would expect MVNO services to
continue to develop where market opportunities exist; and
c) there may be room for improved consumer engagement, to
ensure that consumers are aware of and able to easily take
advantage of competing offers to drive competition.
108
Actions on the state of competition
A1
We will continue to engage with MBIE on the importance of the upcoming
spectrum allocation/auctions for delivering competitive outcomes in the
mobile market.
A2
We have amended the annual monitoring questionnaire to capture
information on the development of MVNO market share and business
sustainability. We also intend to periodically review commercial MVNO
arrangements. This will provide us with greater ongoing visibility of the terms
being offered to MVNOs, and how the commercial terms compare to key price
and non-price dimensions of MVNO access.
A3
We will undertake further work as part of our wider responsibilities under
section 9A and Part 7 of the Telecommunications Act (outside of this study) to:
a) improve our understanding of the extent to which consumers can
and do access, assess and act on relevant information in the
mobile and wider telecommunications markets;
b) assess consumers choices of mobile plans against their usage,
including quantification of the potential savings mobile consumers
could make if they were on plans that better match their usage;
and
c) assess the quality of services provided by mobile suppliers and the
extent to which consumers are actively engaged in the mobile
market, as part of our wider retail service quality programme,
including our ability to review or create retail service quality codes
if appropriate.
109
Chapter 6 Future developments in mobile services
Purpose of this chapter
6.1 This chapter sets out our analysis of some of the key issues relating to the future
development of the mobile marketin particular, those issues raised throughout
the study. These include potential future developments in the supply of mobile
services and our views on their potential effects on competition.
6.2 One of the aims for this study was to gain a better understanding of how mobile
markets are currently performing and developing, and to consider how the mobile
landscape may evolve in the future.
262
This chapter attempts to address the second
aspect of that aim.
6.3 The selection of future developments in this chapter is a subset of the potential
future developments in mobile technology and trends and is not intended to be
exhaustive. 5G and eSIMs are potentially transformative technologies. Network
slicing and increased infrastructure sharing have the potential to alter the
investment profiles for MNOs and access conditions for MVNOs. For a fuller and
broader investigation of future trends please refer to the Red Dawn “Global
Industry Trends Report.
263
5G mobile networks
6.4 5G is the next generation of mobile technology and will require mobile operators to
invest in spectrum and in key network infrastructure, including radio access
network equipment, backhaul and core networks.
264
6.5 The competition between 5G networks in New Zealand and the timing of their
deployment will be heavily dependent on the upcoming spectrum allocations.
Operators must also navigate their proposed 5G infrastructure and network
deployment plans through the statutory process administered by the Government
Communications Security Bureau (GCSB) before they are able to commence
deployment.
265
262
Commerce Commission, “Scope for our study of mobile telecommunications markets in New Zealand”,
(27 March 2018), para 2.
263
Red Dawn Consulting, “Global mobile industry trends: Implications for New Zealand”, (April 2019).
264
Ferry Crijpink, Alexandre Ménard, Halldor Sigurdsson, and Nemanja Vucevic, “The road to 5G: The
inevitable growth of infrastructure cost”, McKinsey & Company, (February 2018).
265
This process is set out in the Telecommunications (Interception Capability and Security) Act 2013.
110
6.6 The statutory process relates to identifying and mitigating any network security
risks that may arise in relation to public telecommunications networks. In
November 2018, following a media release by Spark, the GCSB confirmed that it
had identified a network security risk associated with Spark’s planned use of
Huawei’s equipment within its 5G radio access network.
266
,
267
The GCSB process is
ongoing, and Spark has the opportunity to mitigate the concerns raised by the
GCSB.
6.7 In the event those concerns cannot be mitigated to the GCSB’s satisfaction, the
ultimate decision will rest with the Minister responsible for the GCSB. Only the
Minister responsible for the GCSB can issue a direction to prevent, sufficiently
mitigate, or remove a network security risk identified by the GCSB.
6.8 In making such a direction, the Minister responsible for the GCSB must consult with
the Minister for Trade and Export Growth and the Minister for Broadcasting,
Communications and Digital Media, and must have regard to additional factors
including:
the impact on the MNO of meeting the costs associated with the direction;
the potential consequences that the direction may have on competition
and innovation in telecommunications markets; and
the anticipated benefits to New Zealand from preventing, sufficiently
mitigating, or removing the network security risk.
6.9 The consequences of any decision that has the effect of excluding or restricting the
involvement of Huawei, or any equipment supplier, in the roll-out of 5G networks
could potentially affect the development of competition and the costs of deploying
5G networks in New Zealand.
6.10 In commenting on the GCSB decision, 2degrees has referred to the importance of
multiple vendors to deliver price competition, and that if the GCSB decision is
confirmed and extended to 2degrees, it will be a real disappointment for
competition.
268
Spark has also commented publicly that Huawei had been a very
competitive provider of services that had helped keep the vendor market
honest.
269
266
GCSB statement, (28 November 2018); https://www.gcsb.govt.nz/news/gcsb-statement/.
267
Spark, “GCSB declines Spark’s proposal to use Huawei 5G equipment”, (28 November 2018).
268
https://www.stuff.co.nz/business/108940155/gcsb-declines-huawei-proposal.
269
https://www.stuff.co.nz/business/industries/108261662/kiwi-mobile-phone-users-would-pay-for-5g-ban-
on-chinas-huawei-2degrees-warns.
111
6.11 The roll-out of 5G networks will enable MNOs to further benefit from supply side
economies of scope by offering multiple services over the same infrastructure,
particularly fixed wireless, mobile services and IoT. While there is a lot of industry
and media interest about innovation and new applications using 5G technology in
areas such as production, smart devices, agriculture, and entertainment, the initial
focus from MNOs in New Zealand appears to be in the enhanced capacity for
mobile and fixed wireless broadband.
270
6.12 In its initial phase, 5G is likely to be a basic overlay on existing 4G technology
platforms. The 3rd Generation Partnership Project, which is the international body
that governs cellular standards, has completed and published the 5G technical
standards. This allows for the deployment of fully compliant 5G networks, on top of
existing legacy LTE networks.
6.13 Much like the transitions from 3G to 4G and 4.5G, the initial launch of 5G in
New Zealand is likely to involve the replacement of equipment on existing base
stations. If data usage continues to grow exponentially, and new use cases come
online, higher spectrum frequencies and additional cell sites are likely to be
needed. This may increase the cost of further 5G deployment compared to the
initial phase and potentially increase the complexities and scale for consenting, site
sourcing, site access and environmental consents.
271
6.14 Spark, Vodafone and 2degrees have all indicated that they plan to roll out
competing 5G networks by leveraging their existing network infrastructure.
272
Vodafone has announced that it will initially launch 5G services in select locations in
Auckland, Wellington, Christchurch and Queenstown in December 2019, using its
existing 3.5GHz spectrum holdings (which are due to expire in 2022) and with Nokia
Networks as its technology partner.
273
Spark has also signalled its intention to
launch 5G services as soon as spectrum becomes available.
274
6.15 Dense Air’s recent entry into New Zealand, and its wholesale small-cell
infrastructure sharing approach, potentially provides a complementary service to
the existing MNOs that will improve 4G and 5G services.
270
Spark, “5G: The evolution towards a revolution: Briefing Paper”, (August 2018), p 11.
271
Land Access and the National Environmental Standard for Telecommunication Facilities concerns were
raised in a number of submissions to RSM’s “Preparing for 5G in New Zealand” discussion document.
272
Spark submission on “Preparing for 5G in New Zealand: Discussion Document”, (30 April 2018) p 1,
Vodafone New Zealand submission on “Preparing for 5G in New Zealand: Discussion Document”, (May
2018), p 2, and 2degrees submission on “Preparing for 5G in New Zealand: Discussion Document”, p 2.
273
https://news.vodafone.co.nz/article/vodafone-5g-launch-marks-day-one-new-ownership
274
https://www.sparknz.co.nz/news/fy19-results/.
112
6.16 Spark and Vodafone have also leveraged their mobile infrastructures to deploy IoT
networks in New Zealand, in anticipation of the expected increase in the demand
for IoT applications across a wide range of industry sectors including agriculture,
transport and horticulture. These networks compete with standalone IoT networks
that use different wireless technologies. Standalone IoT networks that have also
launched recently in New Zealand include Kotahinet and Thinkxtra.
eSIMs
6.17 An eSIM is a chip that is soldered directly onto a device’s circuit board and
performs the functions that are today undertaken by a physical SIM card. Instead of
the user having to physically switch SIMs in the device to change networks, this can
be conducted over-the-air or by electronic means instead.
6.18 eSIMs can be embedded in traditional handsets, tablets, wearable technology
(eg, smart watches) and IoT applications.
275
eSIMs offer the opportunity to
eventually make the switching experience seamless as there are no physical
elements to contend with; all aspects of switching can be done remotely.
6.19 eSIMs could benefit MVNOs that wish to bulk transfer their customer base in the
event of switching from one host MNO to another. eSIMs could also enable MVNOs
to differentiate further in niche markets and on pricing, allowing consumers to
seamlessly switch to the best offers available and to stimulate regular switching.
6.20 eSIMs could also create opportunities for global handset makers or OTT players to
become ‘mega MVNOs’ and possibly leverage this position to get better deals from
MNOs. An early example of this is Google’s ProjectFi in the USA.
6.21 There are three prerequisites for the benefits of eSIMs to be realised. Firstly, there
need to be eSIM devices. Secondly, carriers must support eSIMs. This is the most
critical requirement. Lastly, supporting systems are required to enable customers
to switch between providers.
276
6.22 The US Department of Justice recently acknowledged the importance of supporting
eSIMs in its Proposed Final Judgment on the T-Mobile/Sprint merger. One of the
conditions on the merger is that the merged entity, as well as a third party
275
Apple iPhone XR, XS, and XS Max and Google Pixel 2, 2XL, 3, 3XL, 3A and 3A XL and NUU Mobile X5
handsets are currently the only e-SIM capable handsets.
276
Wik Consult, “Economic aspects of embedded SIM for the telecommunications consumer segment”,
(2017).
113
acquiring divested assets (Dish), agrees to support eSIM technology on
smartphones.
277
6.23 Spark is currently the only New Zealand MNO to support eSIMs on its network, but
this support is limited to a select few devices.
278
Vodafone indicated that eSIMs
would be supported on its network by the first quarter of 2019, though this has yet
to happen.
279
2degrees has stated its intention to support eSIMs but has not given
a concrete timeframe.
6.24 Chorus noted in its submission on our Preliminary Findings that The potential
benefits of eSIMs will likely require changes to, or uptake of, new hardware and
processes. They may also require changes to processes for Mobile Number
Portability.
280
Chorus also encouraged us to satisfy ourselves that MNOs
indications that they will support eSIMs are met, enabling the use of devices across
multiple mobile networks.
6.25 Uptake of eSIM devices is predicted to be modest, with the Red Dawn Emerging
Trends Report stating that:
281
The number of eSIM devices could reach anywhere between 148 million to 420
million shipments in 2022…. Smartphones will contribute to nearly two-thirds of all
eSIM device shipments by 2022. Despite such spectacular growth, less than 5% of
smartphones sold globally in 2022 will be eSIM compatible.
6.26 As submissions to the Issues Paper noted, eSIMs may not only affect customers.
Spark highlighted that eSIMs could also potentially alter the distribution channels
of mobile providers and facilitate service providers’ ability to sell mobile plans and
services digitally if they had an agreement with an MVNO and an OTT provider.
282
6.27 Spark also suggested that “…eSIMs may well transform devices smartphones,
iPads, wearables into digital distribution channels for mobile providers that lack
physical stores or pre-existing relationships with retail channels.
283
2degrees
expects that modest cost savings could be realised from eSIMs as the need to
distribute physical SIM cards diminishes.
284
277
See Department of Justice, “Proposed Final Judgment”, (26 July 2019), p 21.
278
https://www.spark.co.nz/esim.
279
https://www.nzherald.co.nz/business/news/article.cfm?c_id=3&objectid=12130793.
280
Chorus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 3.
281
Red Dawn Consulting, “Global mobile industry trends Implications for New Zealand”, (24 April 2019),
p 32.
282
Spark submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 29.
283
Spark submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 27.
284
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 40.
114
6.28 Given the potential of eSIMs to enhance retail and wholesale competition and to
lower switching barriers,
285
we would be concerned with behaviour that sought to
reduce the competitive benefits of eSIMs, for example:
eSIM locking that could increase switching costs for owners of
carrier-locked wearables;
exclusion of other mobile service providers, such as MVNOs; and
limited or restrictive offering of eSIM devices that unduly restrict the
functionality of eSIM devices.
Network slicing
6.29 Network slicing is a form of virtual networking architecture. In simple terms, it
allows network owners to divide up their physical network into multiple virtual
end-to-end networks. This virtualisation enables a variety of different services to be
offered, each able to be carefully tailored.
286
Such services may include IoT, fixed
wireless services, mobile gaming and new forms of MVNO access, as shown in
Figure 21.
Figure 21 5G Network slices
285
See Vocus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 6.
286
Mohammad Asif Habibi et al, “Network Slicing in 5G Mobile Communications: Architecture, Profit,
Modelling and Challenges”, Conference Paper, (August 2017).
115
6.30 Network slicing uses virtualisation technologies such as Network Function
Virtualisation or Software Defined Networking. These technologies offer an
effective way to exploit the benefits of a common network infrastructure, enabling
operators to establish and run multiple network services in parallel.
287
288
6.31 5G network slicing should enable network operators to develop a broader service
portfolio and accordingly diversify, expand and increase ongoing revenue streams
by providing higher quality innovative services that may have a higher ARPU.
6.32 This has the potential to enable non-traditional providers such as Apple and Google
to purchase dedicated network slices to run their services. These providers will still
be reliant on the MNO networks and may provide complementary services rather
than providing an additional competitive constraint on MNOs.
289
6.33 In addition, it is possible that the forthcoming spectrum auction offers up
possibilities for MNOs to create opportunities for more MVNO entry using network
slicing technology.
Infrastructure sharing
6.34 Infrastructure sharing arrangements can result in cost efficiencies by lowering the
cost of network deployment. However, such arrangements can also produce a
range of detriments through reduced infrastructure-based competition. Such
detriments may include higher prices (leading to a reduction in allocative efficiency)
as well as lower levels of innovation (a loss of dynamic efficiency). As a result,
infrastructure sharing will involve a trade-off between different forms of
efficiencies.
6.35 Infrastructure sharing has the potential to affect the economics and speed of LTE
and then 5G deployments, although the overall impact is difficult to predict at this
early stage of development.
6.36 Chorus also highlighted the potential for competition effects due to a risk that
competitive retail tension may decrease with infrastructure sharing agreements
between vertically integrated suppliers. We note Chorus’ concern and reiterate the
287
Matias Richart et al., “Resource Slicing in Virtual Wireless Networks: A Survey”, IEEE Transactions on
Network and Service Management, Vol. 13 Issue 3, (September 2016), p 462.
288
Nokia, “Dynamic end-to-end network slicing for 5G”, (June 2016).
289
Matteo Vincenzi et al, “Multi-Tenant Slicing for spectrum Management on the Road to 5G”, IEEE Wireless
Communications Magazine, Vol. 24, No. 5, (October 2017), p 118- 125. Konstantinos Samdanis et al, “From
Network Sharing to Multi-tenancy: The 5G Network Slice Broker”, IEEE Communications Magazine,
Vol. 54, Issue: 7, (July 2016).
116
point made immediately above that, presently, predicting the likely competition
effects is difficult.
290
6.37 On the other hand, TUANZ’s submission is strongly supportive of infrastructure
sharing, especially in rural areas, noting that effective infrastructure sharing is more
likely to mean that rural end users experience similar levels of connectivity quality
as their urban counterparts.
291
6.38 BEREC, the Body of European Regulators for Electronic Communications, has
recently produced a snapshot of infrastructure sharing arrangements across
European National Regulatory Authorities. BEREC defines infrastructure sharing as
follows:
292
Mobile infrastructure sharing (both passive and active) describes the process by
which operators share infrastructure to deliver a mobile service to end users.
"Passive sharing" is the sharing of the passive elements of network infrastructure
such as masts, sites, cabinet, power, and air conditioning. "Active sharing" is the
sharing of active elements in the radio access network such as antennas and radio
network controllers (RNC).
6.39 The trade-off between the costs of deployment and infrastructure competition may
become more pronounced given the potential densification of cell sites required for
5G.
6.40 In this context, the infrastructure established by the Rural Connectivity Group
(RCG) could be relevant. The RCG plans to deploy 520 cell sites and share spectrum
to improve rural coverage and connectivity under the RBI2 and MBSF. According to
RCG:
293
The cell sites we build will be shared by New Zealand’s mobile network operators –
Vodafone, Spark, 2degrees to provide mobile services from all three mobile
companies and ensure competitive broadband services to rural customers. The
towers will also be open access for wireless internet service providers to utilise. The
infrastructure will allow all operators to share the radio access network equipment
and one set of antennas, meaning the size of the infrastructure can be flexible to
suit the geographic location.
6.41 Depending on its configuration, parts of the RCG infrastructure could be reused for
future deployment of 5G technology by MNOs, at lower cost than a greenfield
implementation. In this way, it is possible that it will be economic to provide 5G
services in areas where it might otherwise be uneconomic.
290
Chorus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 2.
291
TUANZ submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), para 39-39.
292
BEREC, “Report on Infrastructure sharing”, (14 June 2018), BoR (18) 116, p 2.
293
Rural Connectivity Group’s website “Why is RCG unique” - https://www.thercg.co.nz/why-is-rcg-unique/.
117
6.42 Infrastructure sharing arrangements are likely to facilitate 5G coverage, particularly
in more rural areas. 2degrees submitted that although the viability and form of 5G
infrastructure sharing in different regions is yet to be determined, 2degrees expects
that 5G infrastructure sharing will largely follow 4G:
infrastructure competition in areas of high traffic/capacity demand;
passive infrastructure sharing and co-location in areas with moderate to
low traffic/capacity demand; and
active infrastructure sharing in areas of low traffic density, with access to
RCG facilities in RBI2 areas.
294
6.43 2degrees reiterated its preference for issues surrounding infrastructure sharing to
be addressed commercially by the parties in the first instance, due to the extant
uncertainties and complexities. 2degrees sees no requirement for regulatory
intervention at this stage.
295
6.44 We acknowledge the WISPA NZ submission on the Issues Paper that infrastructure
sharing may enable rural consumers to benefit from 5G sooner than having
separate networks, although it is too early to say definitively. In its submission,
WISPA NZ also noted that RCG infrastructure is potentially important to the roll-out
of 5G in rural areas although this depends on whether the intended location of
the RCG towers is suitable to support higher frequency transmissions, and whether
the quality of backhaul available at those towers is adequate to support 5G.
296
6.45 In the case of the RCG joint venture that facilitated improved connectivity under
the RBI2 and the MBSF, the Telecommunications Act provides these programmes
with restrictive trade practices (RTP) authorisation under the Commerce Act.
297
6.46 We note that any new infrastructure sharing arrangements could potentially
require RTP authorisation under the Commerce Act.
6.47 We also note that any new authorised infrastructure sharing to support 5G
deployments could include conditions relating to third party access to shared
infrastructure. In the case of the RCG, it has a Deed of Open Access Undertakings
(the Deed) that includes non-discrimination obligations.
294
2degrees submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 31-33.
295
2degrees submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 4.
296
WISPA NZ submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 3.
297
Section 156AZF of the Telecommunications Act 2001.
118
6.48 The non-discrimination provision in the Deed states that the “RCG will ensure there
is non-discrimination in relation to the supply of a Relevant Service”.
298
The
Relevant Services are Wholesale Tower Co-location and Wholesale Backhaul.
6.49 Where sharing extends to radio spectrum, there may be additional efficiency gains
in terms of spectrum usage. For example, if blocks of spectrum are awarded to
different parties, some spectrum must be used as guard bands to prevent
interference. If a single block of spectrum is awarded and shared, the amount of
spectrum set aside as guard bands may be reduced, freeing up more spectrum to
be used.
Findings on future developments in the mobile market
F21
5G will initially be an evolution over existing networks, and over time network
densification will occur. Investment in 5G may alter the economics of mobile
provision and raises the prospect of greater infrastructure sharing, and larger
incentives to utilise network capacity through MVNO agreements.
F22
eSIM capable devices are likely to become more prevalent, with the potential
to reduce switching costs for both consumers, MNOs and MVNOs. However,
there is the potential for competition to be suppressed if MNOs do not enable
eSIMs or lock eSIMs devices to their network.
F23
We may see more infrastructure sharing. Whether this enhances or suppresses
competition will depend on how the arrangements are structured. We would
expect to see infrastructure sharing proposals that raise potential competition
concerns come to us for authorisation.
298
RCG, “Deed of Open Access Undertakings for RBI2”, clause 5.1.
119
Chapter 7 Regulated services
Purpose of this chapter
7.1 This chapter sets out our findings and actions concerning the five regulated services
that currently relate to the mobile market, in light of submissions received during
the study, the completion of the Schedule 3 reviews of Designated and Specified
Services in June 2016, and National Roaming in September 2018.
Mobile termination access services
7.2 MTAS are the termination services a fixed or mobile network operator needs to
purchase to allow its subscribers to communicate with the subscribers of a mobile
network. The MTAS service is illustrated in Figure 22.
Figure 22 Mobile termination access service
7.3 A mobile network needs to be able to interconnect with other networks to ensure
that its subscribers can communicate.
7.4 MTAS is a designated access service under Schedule 1 of the Telecommunications
Act, which allows us to determine the price and non-price terms of the service.
MTAS includes termination of voice calls and SMS.
7.5 In 2011, we finalised an STD in respect of the MTAS, in which we set mobile
termination rates (MTRs) for voice calls and SMS. These are summarised in Table 8.
Table 8 Mobile termination rates
Effective from
6 May 2011
1 Oct 2011
1 Apr 2012
1 Apr 2013
1 Apr 2014
Voice (cpm)
7.48
5.88
3.97
3.72
3.56
SMS (cpSMS)
0.06
Source: Commerce Commission Decision 724
120
7.6 Every five years, we are required to review whether Schedule 1 services should
remain in Schedule 1. The MTAS service was last reviewed in 2015 and we
concluded that it should remain in Schedule 1.
7.7 Our reasons for keeping MTAS in Schedule 1 included that each MNO has a
monopoly over the termination of calls on its network under the calling party pays
principle, and that the ability to increase MTRs can distort downstream
competition.
299
Our next scheduled review of MTAS is September 2020.
7.8 Chorus reiterated the points made in its submission on our Terms of Reference for
the Mobile Market Study, that the regulated reductions in voice MTRs were set via
benchmarking in 2011 and the reductions finished in 2014, and that international
evidence indicates that the cost of mobile termination is decreasing.
300
Chorus also
indicated that it was concerned with above-cost termination rates which it argued
leads to a risk of a wealth transfer from fixed-line only RSPs to RSPs who operate
mobile networks”.
301
7.9 Vocus supported the Chorus position in its cross-submission.
302
Both parties would
like to see a review of MTRs brought forward prior to the scheduled Commission
review of MTAS in 2020. Chorus had previously argued that the MTAS rate was high
relative to overseas comparators and that it was distortionary, compared with the
real costs of servicing mobile calls, particularly fixed-to-mobile calling rates.
303
7.10 In several overseas jurisdictions, MTRs are set on a pure long run incremental
cost
304
pricing principle. Our current pricing principle under Schedule 1 of the
Telecommunications Act is total service long run incremental cost, which may
result in different pricing calculations.
7.11 We note that overseas jurisdictions have significantly lowered their MTRs over the
past few years, including comparator countries used to set our benchmark price in
our 2011 MTAS STD. For example, Australia was one of the comparators we used
299
Commerce Commission, “Consideration of whether to commence an investigation into whether to omit
the Mobile Termination Access Services from Schedule 1 of the Telecommunications Act 2001”,
(23 September 2015), para 4.
300
Chorus, “Submission in response to the Commerce Commission’s Mobile Market Study Terms of
Reference”, (30 November 2017); Vocus Communications, “Mobile Market Study Scoping”,
(30 November 2017).
301
Chorus submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 3.
302
Vocus cross-submission on Preliminary Findings paper, (19 July 2019), para 32.
303
Chorus submission on the Issues paper, (26 October 2018), p 6.
304
The forward-looking costs incurred over the long-run which are directly attributable to a defined
increment of service.
121
and had a benchmark rate of A5.8 cents per minute.
305
However, in 2015 the ACCC
set a new TSLRIC-based MTR for voice calls at A1.7 cents per minute.
306
7.12 We remain committed to first undertake the five-yearly review of MTAS scheduled
for 2020, prior to commencing a re-benchmarking of the prices in the MTAS STD. In
that review, we intend to consider the competition implications of emerging
services such as OTT communication services.
7.13 We have previously noted the development and adoption of OTT services utilising
Voice-over-Internet Protocol. OTT services can potentially be a substitute for
conventional mobile services. OTT services incur no termination charges when both
parties have the OTT service on their device.
7.14 In our 2015 review of MTAS, we referred to evidence from the European
Commission and the ACCC that, although OTT services were emerging as a
potential constraint on MTAS, OTT services were not yet effective substitutes.
307
We noted that mobile voice traffic in New Zealand continued to increase, although
SMS traffic had started to fall in recent years. We concluded that we did not have
enough evidence to determine whether OTT services are an effective substitute for
mobile services.
7.15 Since 2015, mobile voice traffic has continued to increase in New Zealand and SMS
traffic has continued to decline. As we noted in our 2017 Annual Monitoring
Report, the decline in SMS volumes is expected to continue given the increasing
popularity of various OTT messaging services like Facebook Messenger, iMessage,
WhatsApp and Viber.
308
7.16 Analysys Mason’s Connected Consumer Survey reported that 81% of
New Zealanders with a smartphone use OTT services, with messaging services
being the most common.
309
305
Commerce Commission, Decision 724, (5 May 2011), p 71.
306
ACCC, “Mobile Terminating Access Service Final Access Determination: Final Decision”, (August 2015).
307
Commerce Commission, “Consideration of whether to commence an investigation into whether to omit
the Mobile Termination Access Services from Schedule 1 of the Telecommunications Act 2001”,
(23 September 2015), para 46-49.
308
Commerce Commission, “Annual Telecommunications Monitoring Report: 2017 Key Facts”,
(20 December 2017), p 25.
309
Analysys Mason, “Connected Consumer Survey 2018: mobile customer satisfaction in Australia and
New Zealand”, (February 2019).
122
7.17 We note that the ACCC has recently decided to retain the MTAS voice termination
service as a regulated service, but has deregulated the MTAS SMS termination
service, as OTT messaging services are now considered to be effective substitutes
for SMS.
310
National roaming
7.18 National roaming allows customers of one mobile network to use another network
when they are outside their own service provider’s coverage area.
7.19 National roaming is a wholesale mobile access service which allows customers on
one MNO to roam on the network of another MNO. Roaming is typically used by
new entrants or smaller MNOs to offer national coverage in the mobile markets.
7.20 When it first entered the mobile market in New Zealand, 2degrees had deployed a
mobile network which covered 47% of New Zealand’s population. To be able to
offer national coverage, 2degrees initially relied on roaming on Vodafone’s mobile
network, which 2degrees secured through a commercial agreement. 2degrees has
since invested in expanding the footprint of its own network, and now has coverage
like that of its competitors.
7.21 In 2018 we considered the roaming service as part of the five-yearly reviews of
services in Schedule 1 of the Telecommunications Act. Our final decision was to
retain national roaming as a specified service.
7.22 We concluded that there may be potential competition issues arising from the
allocation of spectrum for 5G. A new entrant would likely require a roaming
arrangement to provide immediate coverage while it built out its physical
network.
311
7.23 We also noted that the regulated service is specified only, which means that we do
not set price terms. This mitigates the risk that roaming will distort investment
incentives facing both the MNO relying on roaming and the MNO supplying
roaming. However, roaming as a regulated service acts as an important backstop in
the event of commercial negotiations failing.
310
ACCC, “Domestic Mobile Terminating Access Service Declaration Inquiry: Final Report”, (June 2019).
311
Commerce Commission, “Review of National Roaming: Final decision on consideration of deregulation of
national roaming”, (4 September 2018), p 7-8.
123
Mobile co-location
7.24 Mobile co-location is a service that enables an MNO to install mobile network
transmission and reception equipment on the mast of another MNO (see Figure
23).
Figure 23 Mobile co-location
7.25 In New Zealand, mobile co-location is a specified service and has been subject to an
STD since 2008.
312
We reviewed whether mobile co-location should remain a
specified service in 2016 and concluded that it should remain in Schedule 1.
313
7.26 We noted that the ability to co-locate equipment on the infrastructure of another
MNO facilitates the efficient deployment of mobile technology by sharing the cost
of facilities such as towers and masts. The ability to share such costs is likely to
312
Commerce Commission, “Standard Terms Determination for Co-location on Cellular Mobile Transmission
Sites, Schedule 1 Mobile Co-location Service Description”, (11 December 2008).
313
Commerce Commission, “Review of Designated and Specified Services under Schedule 1 of the
Telecommunications Act 2001”, (5 July 2016), para 154.
124
become increasingly important as a mechanism for reaching more remote areas
with current and new technology such as 4G LTE and 5G.
314
7.27 We also noted that there had been increased use of co-location, particularly during
the period from 2012 to 2015, and that co-location had been occurring both on RBI
and non-RBI sites.
7.28 Under RBI1, the Government appointed and funded Vodafone to upgrade existing
cell sites and build new cell sites in rural areas. Under that arrangement, Vodafone
must offer co-location services in respect of cell sites funded through RBI1. MBIE
has reported that 154 new cell sites have been built under RBI1, all of which allow
for co-location by competing operators. In addition, 387 cell sites have been
upgraded.
315
7.29 Co-location on existing cell sites can be more challenging than on new cell sites, as
existing cell site infrastructure may have been built to accommodate a single set of
equipment. The installation of additional equipment may require strengthening of
the mast infrastructure and may also result in the equipment being located further
down the mast, leading to reduced coverage.
7.30 The second stage of the RBI programme (RBI2) is further extending mobile
coverage in rural areas, while the Government’s MBSF is providing greater mobile
coverage along state highways and in tourism destinations where no coverage
currently exists. MBIE reports that 26 tourist sites have received new mobile
coverage, 238km of State Highways have improved coverage, and 25 mobile towers
are now complete. Overall, 38,662 rural homes and businesses can now access
improved broadband.
316
7.31 The RCG is a joint venture between the three MNOs appointed by the Government
to build the infrastructure to extend mobile coverage under the RBI2 and MBSF
programmes. This differs from the RBI1 scheme in that under the RCG model, the
three MNOs will share radio access network equipment and antennas on each site
constructed by the RCG.
314
Commerce Commission, “Review of Designated and Specified Services under Schedule 1 of the
Telecommunications Act 2001”, (5 July 2016), para X28.1.
315
See https://www.mbie.govt.nz/assets/aae2c79c33/december-18-broadband-quarterly-update.pdf.
316
Crown Infrastructure Partners “Quarterly Connectivity Update Q2 to June 2019” (June 2019), p4.
125
Number portability
7.32 Introduced in 2007, the designated local and mobile number portability service
allows customers to keep their number when switching between service providers.
We reviewed whether number portability should remain a specified service in 2016
and concluded that it should remain in Schedule 1.
317
7.33 The New Zealand Telecommunications Forum Inc. administers the scheme, and the
number portability determination ensures that the process for porting a fixed or
mobile telephone number while switching providers is easy to initiate, and that end
users are not left without communications for a long period.
7.34 We plan to complete our next 5-yearly Schedule 3 review of the service by
June 2021.
Backhaul
7.35 Backhaul services that support mobile networks are not currently regulated under
Schedule 1 of the Telecommunications Act.
318
7.36 MNOs rely on backhaul services to connect cell sites and other network nodes.
319
Such connectivity supports both mobile services and fixed wireless services and
may take the form of actively managed wholesale services (such as leased line
bandwidth services), or passive services (such as the direct fibre access service
(DFAS)).
7.37 We understand that Spark and Vodafone self-supply some of their backhaul
requirements, but also acquire backhaul from other parties such as Chorus. In
2017, 2degrees announced that it had selected Chorus as the provider of wholesale
backhaul services to support 2degrees fixed and mobile services.
320
7.38 Fibre-based backhaul is the main technology used to support the supply of high
speed mobile data services. We expect fibre backhaul to increase in importance
317
Commerce Commission, “Review of Designated and Specified Services under Schedule 1 of the
Telecommunications Act 2001”, (5 July 2016), para 150.
318
The backhaul services regulated under Schedule 1 of the Telecommunications Act 2001 are specific to
copper regulated access services UCLL, UCLFS and UBA.
319
Backhaul in this context refers to a class of services used to transport traffic between active elements (ie,
nodes) of a mobile or fixed-line network. Backhaul services may be used anywhere within the mobile or
fixed-line operators’ network nationally (eg, Chorus’ regional transport service (CRT)), regionally (eg,
intra-candidate area backhaul service (ICABS)) and locally (eg, DFAS).
320
2degrees media release “2degress announces Chorus as primary provider of national backhaul” (8 August
2017)
126
with the deployment of 5G mobile networks because of the need for low latency
and high capacity backhaul.
7.39 We note that 2degrees expressed some concern over backhaul pricing in Chorus/
Local Fibre Company (LFC) areas, where Chorus and the LFCs are in effect
monopoly suppliers of mobile backhaul.
321
We also note that Part 6 of the
Telecommunications Act provides for the price-quality regulation of DFAS (which
may be used as backhaul) for Chorus.
7.40 The direct fibre access services that Chorus and the LFCs provide to mobile
operators are subject to maximum prices set in 2011 under the terms of the UFB
contracts. Those prices will be frozen at the 2019 rates and be subject to annual
inflation adjustments from 1 December 2019 and ending on the day before
1 January 2022. Thereafter, LFCs will not be subject to price-quality regulation, but
as we note above, Chorus will. We may review the effectiveness of the regulation
of backhaul services that are subject to price-quality regulation upon completion of
the first regulatory period no later than 31 December 2025.
7.41 We indicated in our s9A backhaul study that we will continue to monitor
developments in the backhaul sector going forward.
322
Among other reasons, as
noted above, fibre-based backhaul will become increasingly important for the
successful completion of competing 5G networks.
7.42 We note that wireless backhaul may also be an alternative, particularly where fibre
is unavailable or impractical. The use of wireless backhaul will be dependent on the
availability of appropriate spectrum and local conditions.
7.43 The level of competitive intensity in the supply of backhaul services varies around
New Zealand. In some regions, there are several competing backhaul networks,
such as Chorus, Spark, Vodafone, Vocus, Vector, and the LFCs. In other areas, the
options are more limited, and the likely development of small-cell infrastructure to
support some 5G use cases could further challenge the competitive dynamic for
backhaul services in New Zealand.
7.44 As noted above, the MNOs rely on backhaul services from Chorus and the other
LFCs to supply mobile and fixed wireless services. To the extent that mobile and
fixed wireless services emerge as a competitive threat to fibre-based access
services supplied by Chorus and the LFCs, the incentives to supply backhaul services
may change.
321
2degrees submission on the Preliminary Findings paper, (28 June 2019), p 4.
322
Commerce Commission, “Section 9A Backhaul services study Our findings”, (11 June 2019) p 12-13, p 35.
127
7.45 In effect, Chorus and the LFCs would be supplying an upstream input to
competitors in a downstream market. This may become increasingly significant in
the context of 5G, as fixed wireless services are expected to be an important early
use case supported by 5G deployments.
7.46 We also note that some Chorus backhaul products within Chorus’ fibre candidate
areas (eg, DFAS) are likely to be regulated fibre fixed-line access services under
Part 6 of the Telecommunications Act and thus be subject to the maximum
allowable revenue set by the new regulatory regime for fibre.
323
7.47 The other LFCs will not be subject to price-quality regulation but will be subject to
information disclosure requirements. MBIE has been consulting on the proposed
content of regulations to be made under section 226 of the Telecommunications
Act that will apply to each regulated fibre service provider.
324
7.48 We undertook a section 9A study into backhaul services and released our findings
on 11 June 2019.
325
We indicated in those findings that we intend to “continue to
monitor the availability and prices of the different commercial backhaul services in
Chorus’ portfolio on an ongoing basis as part of our section 9A functions.
326
We
noted further that we would consider the need for any changes to all regulated
backhaul services as part of the scheduled review of certain regulated copper
fixed-line services to be completed by no later than 31 December 2025.
327
7.49 In conclusion, our analysis of the current state of mobile market competition, likely
future developments, and the work we have commissioned by external experts on
emerging trends in the mobile market (which has been published separately),
328
confirm our view that the current regulatory settings are fit for purpose. Therefore,
our findings on our regulated services are set out below.
323
The scope of the FFLAS that are regulated under Part 6 will be set in regulations that are still to be made.
324
See https://www.mbie.govt.nz/have-your-say/exposure-draft-of-regulations-section-226-
telecommunications-act/.
325
Commerce Commission, “Section 9A Backhaul services study Our findings”, (11 June 2019).
326
Commerce Commission, “Section 9A Backhaul services study Our findings”, (11 June 2019), p 13.
327
Commerce Commission, “Section 9A Backhaul services study Our findings”, (11 June 2019), p 12.
328
See https://comcom.govt.nz/__data/assets/pdf_file/0033/146679/RDC-Mobile-industry-trends-14-May-
2019.PDF.
128
Findings on regulated services
F24
Our review of the current market conditions, and likely future developments,
has not identified sufficient grounds for us to bring forward our planned
reviews of regulated services. The scheduled reviews for these services are set
out in Table 1 in Chapter 2.
F25
Backhaul services, whether metropolitan or between national network nodes,
appear not to have constrained the competitiveness or development of mobile
services to date. However, we recognise the potential for bottlenecks to
develop as mobile (eg, 5G), fibre technologies (eg, passive optical networking)
and fibre regulation undergo a period of significant change.