Low Pay Britain 
Nye Cominei, Charlie McCurdy, Gregory Thwaites & Rui Vieira-Marques
April 
Funded by
Improving low-paid work through higher minimum
standards
Citation
If you are using this document in your own writing, our preferred citation is:
N. Cominetti et al, Low Pay Britain 2023 :
Improving low-paid work through higher minimum standards , The Resolution
Foundation, April 2023
Permission to share
This document is published under the Creative Commons Attribution Non
Commercial No Derivatives 3.0 England and Wales Licence. This allows anyone
to download, reuse, reprint, distribute, and/or copy Economy 2030 Inquiry
publications without written permission subject to the conditions set out in the
Creative Commons Licence.
For commercial use, please contact: info@resolutionfoundation.org
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank the following people for taking part
in helpful discussions: Anna Stansbury, Jonathan Wadsworth, Xiaowei
Xu, Tony Wilson, Afzal Rahman, Mark Williams, Maria Koumenta,
Rebecca Florisson, Eugenia Migliori, David Massey, Tim Butcher, and
Eduin Latimer. Any errors are the authors’ own.
ONS crown copyright
This work contains statistical data from ONS which is Crown
Copyright. The use of the ONS statistical data in this work does not
imply the endorsement of the ONS in relation to the interpretation
or analysis of the statistical data. This work uses research datasets
which may not exactly reproduce National Statistics aggregates.
This research uses data from an online survey of 2,011 private-sector
employees conducted by YouGov. The figures presented from the
online survey have been analysed independently by the Resolution
Foundation. The views expressed here are not the views of YouGov.
2The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
The Economy 2030 Inquiry
The Economy 2030 Inquiry is a collaboration between the Resolution
Foundation and the Centre for Economic Performance at the London School of
Economics, funded by the Nuffield Foundation. The Inquiry’s subject matter is
the nature, scale, and context for the economic change facing the UK during the
2020s. Its goal is not just to describe the change that Covid-19, Brexit, the Net
Zero transition and technology will bring, but to help the country and its policy
makers better understand and navigate it against a backdrop of low productivity
and high inequality. To achieve these aims the Inquiry is leading a two-year
national conversation on the future of the UK economy, bridging rigorous
research, public involvement and concrete proposals. The work of the Inquiry
will be brought together in a final report in 2023 that will set out a renewed
economic strategy for the UK to enable the country to successfully navigate the
decade ahead, with proposals to drive strong, sustainable and equitable growth,
and significant improvements to peoples living standards and well-being.
The Nuffield Foundation
The Nuffield Foundation is an independent charitable trust with a mission to
advance social well-being. It funds research that informs social policy, primarily
in Education, Welfare, and Justice. It also funds student programmes that
provide opportunities for young people to develop skills in quantitative and
scientific methods. The Nuffield Foundation is the founder and co-funder of the
Nuffield Council on Bioethics and the Ada Lovelace Institute. The Foundation
has funded this project, but the views expressed are those of the authors and
not necessarily the Foundation. Visit www.nuffieldfoundation.org.
3The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
4
Contents
Acknowledgements 2
Executive Summary 5
Section 1
Introduction 15
Section 2
The uneven distribution of ‘good’ work 21
Section 3
The impact of a rising minimum wage 33
Section 4
Minimum standards beyond the minimum wage 42
Section 5
Improving low-paid work through higher mininum standards 53
Section 6
Conclusion 70
Annex 1: Low pay in 2022 71
Annex 2: An illustrative example of a new Statutory Sick Pay 73
system
Annex 3: Thinking about optimal minimum wages 74
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
Executive Summary
After a decade and a half of relative economic decline, Britain
needs a new economic strategy. And good work must be at its
heart – an explicit goal, not a hoped-for by-product of growth. This
is a necessary precondition for a strategy that offers a credible
promise of shared prosperity in the years ahead, strengthening not
just our economy but our society and democracy too.
Why is good work so important? Because at the moment too many
lower earners do not have it. Their job satisfaction has fallen (in
stark contrast to higher earners), even as the minimum wage has
risen. Too often they are not treated with dignity and respect, with
little or no protection from unexpected changes to the shifts they
work and the wages they take home. And they lack many of the
things that higher earners take for granted: the lack of adequate
sick pay, for example, means illness is bad for the financial, as
well as physical, health of low-paid workers in a way most higher
earners never experience.
This paper considers what it would mean to put good work centre
stage. It requires us to go far beyond the narrow focus this century
on a higher minimum wage, because although pay is crucial it is far
from all that matters. It necessitates a radically different approach
to the trade-offs that are inherent if real progress is to be made:
better jobs for some will mean higher prices for others. And good
work must be seen as part of a route to achieving wider economic
policy objectives – an integral part of an economic strategy that
engages with what the UK produces and consumes, alongside who
benefits from it doing so.
Low Pay Britain 2023 | Executive Summary 5
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
This Low Pay Britain report is the 13
th
in an annual series, where
we take stock of the state of low-paid work. This edition also forms
part of our Economy 2030 Inquiry, which seeks to set out what a
plausible economic strategy that tackles the UK’s twin problems
of high inequality and low growth might be. It is an argument for
putting good work centre stage, and a policy agenda for doing so.
Too many low-paying jobs do not offer good work, and
job satisfaction among low earners has fallen
Work means very different things to lower and higher earners:
not enough of the former enjoy the basics of dignity, respect and
security that the latter take for granted.
There is no single thing that makes a job ‘good’ or ‘bad’, but we can
confidently list as ‘good’ qualities like security, autonomy, having a
voice in the workplace, and opportunities for progression. Volatile
pay, intense work, or a lack of certainty over when you work are
‘bad’. These aspects of job quality are distributed very unequally.
Workers with hourly pay in the bottom quintile of the distribution
are more than twice as likely as workers in the highest paid quintile
(38 per cent compared to 15 per cent) to say they have little or no
autonomy at work; four times as likely to experience volatility in
their hours and pay (22 per cent compared to 6 per cent); and four
times as likely to be working fewer hours than they would like (17
per cent compared to 4 per cent).
There are also some less obvious ways in which work is harder
for those on low pay. Many in well-paid jobs take for granted the
everyday flexibility to be able to take time off to deal with an
emergency at home. But that isn’t possible in many low-paid jobs.
In a new survey of 2,000 private-sector employees, more than half
(56 per cent) of those earning less than £20,000 per year said that
if they had to miss work for a day due to a family emergency then
they wouldn’t be paid – five times the rate among workers earning
above £60,000 (12 per cent).
Some of these differences are hard to eliminate, but their breadth
and scale are far harder to justify. Despite a rising minimum wage,
job satisfaction among the lowest-paid workers has fallen in
the past three decades, while it has been stable for the highest
Low Pay Britain 2023 | Executive Summary 6
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
earners. Thirty years ago, low-paid workers enjoyed a significant
job satisfaction premium (of 16 percentage points) over higher-
paid workers, which has now disappeared, as low-paid work has
become more stressful and intense.
Minimum standards in the UK often lag other rich
countries
The minimum standards different countries set in their labour
markets matter greatly for the lived experience of work, particularly
for lower earners. While many things in the workplace are hard
to regulate (like the autonomy workers have over specific tasks),
which is why broader questions about worker power are central
to a good work agenda, there are many important areas where
universal minimum standards can make a difference. Pay is the
most obvious of these (i.e. the minimum wage), but other areas
include sick pay, protection against hours insecurity, and also
some less obvious areas like parental pay and minimum holiday
entitlements.
While legal minimums in these areas are generally universal in the
UK, it is mainly low earners who would benefit from raising them.
Higher earners tend to be offered occupational entitlements far
exceeding the statutory minimum. For example, more than half
(56 per cent) of private-sector employees earning below £20,000
expect to receive only statutory sick pay (SSP) or nothing at all if
they have to take a week off work through illness, compared to
around a tenth of those earning above £50,000. Those earning
less than £123 per week (1.6 million workers) are ineligible for
any statutory sick pay at all. Similarly, two-thirds (65 per cent) of
female workers under the age of 45 earning below £20,000 expect
to either receive only statutory maternity pay or not be paid at all
if they took a nine-month period of maternity leave, compared to
three-in-ten (28 per cent) of those with an income over £40,000
(the rest of whom would expect to benefit from a more generous
occupational maternity pay scheme).
This divergence between the experiences of higher and lower
earners in part simply reflects how low the UK’s minimum labour
market standards often are compared to those set in similar
economies. SSP in the UK is just £109.40 per week. This is already
Low Pay Britain 2023 | Executive Summary 7
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
low, but combined with the three-day waiting period policy (i.e. SSP
provides nothing for the first three days), a worker off sick for a
week would get just £43.76 - just 11 per cent of the wage someone
working full-time on the minimum wage would earn (£390). The
replacement rate of equivalent schemes in other countries is
significantly higher: across the OECD, the median replacement
rate of mandatory sickness benefit (i.e. statutory sick pay or its
equivalent) for a four-week sickness absence is 64 per cent for a
private-sector worker on average pay, compared to 11 per cent in
the UK.
Similarly, the replacement rate of statutory maternity pay is lower
in the UK than other rich countries. Statutory maternity pay would
replace 27 per cent of earnings over a one-year maternity leave for
a woman earning average pay in the private-sector, compared to
a median replacement rate of 40 per cent across OECD countries
(and there are 14 OECD countries where the replacement rate is
above 50 per cent). The UK sets no minimum levels of advance
notice for when workers must be notified of their shifts, and also
offers workers a below-average number of minimum holiday days –
28, compared to the OECD median of 31.
And in some areas the UK has actively gone backwards, in 2011
extending to two years (previously one year) the period during
which a worker has no protection from unfair dismissal. Currently
2.4 million workers in the bottom hourly pay quintile have been
working for their employer for less than two years and have no
protection against unfair dismissal.
A ‘good work’ agenda must provide a broad-based
platform for treating lower earners with dignity
It is clear that pay isn’t the only thing that matters at work. This is
not just true in an abstract sense – things like being treated with
dignity and being given adequate time off have a real and tangible
value to workers. We surveyed workers on what, other than higher
pay, would make a positive difference to them at work, and more
than half said they would be willing to turn down a pay rise for
this improvement – some as much as a 10 per cent rise. The most
commonly-chosen improvements were more paid holiday, fewer
hours, work to be less intense, more flexible hours, and a greater
Low Pay Britain 2023 | Executive Summary 8
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
ability to work from home. Not far behind these was being treated
with more dignity at work – chosen by one-in-20 respondents.
What concretely would a platform that aims to make progress look
like? The priority areas would be sick pay, hours and pay volatility,
and unfair dismissal, each of which can be broadly seen as policies
relating to security at work. On sick pay, we must improve the
level of SSP and make it universally available. We propose an
earnings replacement approach, where SSP is paid at 65 per
cent of a workers usual earnings (close to the median OECD
replacement rate over a four- week sickness absence of 64 per
cent). Furthermore, the number of ‘waiting days’ should be reduced
from three to one – meaning workers would receive SSP from the
second day. For a full-time minimum wage worker facing a week off
sick, this system would mean SSP of £203.19, compared to £43.76
under the current system. This would be a significant benefit to
the approximately 4.1 million workers in the private-sector who
expect to rely on SSP for protection when they are sick or the 1.6
million workers who earn too little to be eligible.
On hours and pay volatility, we propose a right to a contract with
minimum hours (reflecting a workers usual work pattern), a right
to at least two weeks’ advance notice of shifts, and compensation
for late changes. This would be of benefit to the 1.1 million workers
on a zero-hours contract and the 7.2 million workers who say they
are anxious about unexpected changes in their hours of work (of
whom 2 million are in the bottom hourly pay quintile). And the
period after which unfair dismissal applies should be lowered to
one year, as was the case until 2011. Both of these sets of changes
are about treating low earners with greater dignity and respect,
and giving them the kinds of security and control that higher
earners take for granted.
Beyond these priority areas, there is also a case for raising the
UK’s floor when it comes to parental pay and raising the minimum
holiday entitlement, where in both cases the UK should consider
matching the median entitlements available in other OECD
countries.
Low Pay Britain 2023 | Executive Summary 9
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
A rising minimum wage has had a transformative
impact on the pay of the lowest earners
If the idea of raising standards to ensure wider access to good jobs
sounds far-fetched, we should remember that when it comes to
pay that is exactly what we have done. The improvements made to
the minimum wage in recent years have transformed the low pay
landscape in the UK.
Since the National Living Wages 2016 introduction, the minimum
wage has been lifted rapidly. In 2015 the adult minimum wage
was worth 54.5 per cent of median hourly pay among the group
covered; in 2022 this was 62.9 per cent. The UK’s minimum wage
is now among the highest in the world – currently the only rich
countries with higher minimum wages (relative to median pay
among full-time workers in those countries) are France, New
Zealand and Korea. Based on the target path of the UK minimum
wage, by 2024 the UK’s minimum wage will have passed France and
Koreas current minimum wage levels.
Raising the wage floor has hugely reduced hourly pay inequality.
The proportion of employees in ‘low’ hourly pay (earning below
two-thirds of the median) fell to 9 per cent in 2022 (2.5 million
workers), by far the lowest since our data series begins in the
late 1960s, and has more than halved from 21 per cent in 2015
(5.5 million workers). It has also fundamentally reshaped the
distribution of pay growth – in the 1980s and 1990s, the highest
earners saw the fastest pay growth and the lowest earners the
slowest; this pattern has been reversed in the minimum wage era.
Of course, the usual caveats apply, namely that the minimum wage
only applies to the hourly pay of employees, and so has a limited
impact on weekly pay inequality, and no direct impact at all on self-
employed workers. But this is what a transformational policy looks
like. And fast upratings are set to continue: the Government has
set the Low Pay Commission a target of raising the National Living
Wage to ‘bite’ of two-thirds of median hourly pay among the group
covered by 2024.
Low Pay Britain 2023 | Executive Summary 10
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
We should continue to raise the minimum wage,
although we need to think harder about when to stop
uprating
Along with much-needed broadening of how policy improves
lower-paid work, a good work agenda would continue to build on
the success of the minimum wage. The current minimum target
period ends in 2024, so policy makers need to decide this year
what the next target should be. Based on the record so far – of
significant wage gains, and negative employment effects still
proving ‘elusive’ – it makes sense to set a new, higher target.
Continuing at the current pace of uprating (of raising the ‘bite’ of
the minimum wage – its value relative to median hourly pay – at
1.2 percentage points per year) would imply a target path reaching
a bite of 73 per cent by 2029, the likely end of the next parliament.
On current OBR forecasts that would mean reaching a value of
£13.12 in that year, or £25,660 per year for a full-time worker. The
pace of uprating matters, because it determines how long it
would take to row back from an uprating ‘overshoot’ – which if we
keep raising the minimum wage is likely to happen at some point.
Raising the bite at 1.2 percentage points per year would allow
policy makers to ‘undo’ annual upratings fairly quickly by freezing
the minimum wage in cash terms.
But importantly, alongside a new target path, we need a much
clearer framework for deciding when to stop uprating. The
Governments current remit is vague: the Low Pay Commission
is asked to stop raising the minimum wage relative to typical pay
when there is ‘significant’ risk to the employment prospects of
affected workers. But ‘significant’ is not defined and too often it
is taken to mean any meaningful negative effect on employment.
This is not the appropriate test: it is right to avoid lastingly locking
groups out of work given the impacts on health and well-being,
but the lost wage gains from not proceeding with further minimum
wage rises should not be ignored. (We should not turn down a
wage gain for millions for the sake of lowering unemployment by
a couple of hundred, for example.) While there is no right answer
to calibrating the employment versus wages trade-off, it is time
for the Government to think harder about what is acceptable and
provide that steer to the Low Pay Commission, before rather than
Low Pay Britain 2023 | Executive Summary 11
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
after disemployment effects are found. Targeting an employment
elasticity of -0.3 (where 30 per cent of the wage gains to minimum
wage workers are lost to lower employment) may be appropriate.
We need to think broadly when it comes to the trade-
offs involved in raising minimum standards
As with the employment effects that worry policy makers when
it comes to the minimum wage, other policy areas also involve
specific trade-offs. For example, a sick pay scheme needs to
balance the income protection offered to workers against
potential incentives to ‘shirk. On that question, our judgement is
that SSP could be significantly more generous while still offering
strong work incentives. But this would still mean that UK workers
would take more sick days – because they could afford to do so.
At present, sick days in the UK amount to 4.5 days per worker per
year, compared to 9.2 in France and 11.7 in Germany, both countries
whose sick pay systems offer better income protection.
Overall, our proposals to raise minimum labour standards will lead
to higher labour costs, and it will be important for policy makers
to view them in the round. The Low Pay Commission should be
tasked with evaluating impacts, and with advising Government on
the timing and specifics of each policy area (i.e. we should apply
the policy mechanism used to set the minimum wage to other
areas).
But important as these ‘micro’ considerations are, we need to
also think bigger about the trade-offs involved in raising minimum
employment standards. In doing so, production costs would rise in
sectors employing large numbers of low earners, including retail,
hospitality and other non-tradeable services, and social care.
Some of this would be passed on to consumers in the shape of
higher prices (although the minimum wage literature tells us that
other margins of adjustment, like profits and productivity, also
apply). This in turn might lead to lower consumption and output
in these sectors (or, in the case of social care, a higher demand on
the public finances). And production patterns may also change
– either in terms of how we produce (for example, production
might become more capital intensive) or in what we produce (for
example, the UK might produce less labour-intensive services).
Low Pay Britain 2023 | Executive Summary 12
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
We should take these effects seriously but, rather than panic
about them, integrate them into a wider renewed economic
strategy. First, the higher standards and prices trade-off is simply
spelling out the clear distributional picture when it comes to
raising employment standards. The benefits would mainly flow to
lower-income households: among the poorest fifth of households,
hospitality and leisure comprise a quarter of employment,
compared to just a tenth of employment among the richest
households. The costs, meanwhile, would be disproportionately
borne by richer households, who spend a larger share than
poorer households on those services (households in the top
fifth of the income distribution spend 35 per cent of their money
on hospitality and leisure, compared to 23 per cent among the
poorest fifth of households).
A second reason is that, to the extent that changes in prices led
to shifts in consumption behaviour, this would make the UK less
exceptional compared to other countries. In the UK, hospitality
(hotels and restaurants) is fairly cheap compared to other goods
and services we consume (hospitality is 10 per cent cheaper in
the UK than if the ratio of prices in hospitality to other goods
in services was the same as in Europe as a whole); perhaps as
a result, we consume a lot of it compared with most European
countries (hospitality comprises 10 per cent of our consumption,
compared to 6 per cent across the EU). Overall, therefore, the
wider changes which could flow from higher minimum standards
in the labour market are consistent with a wider strategy to raise
growth and to reduce inequality.
We can and should improve work for low earners
It is easy to congratulate ourselves on the progress the UK has
made on the minimum wage. And of course, we should – this
progress has been real and meaningful. But we need to recognise
that the broader challenges facing lower earners means the UK is
a long way from having put ‘good jobs’ centre stage. Rather than
just celebrating the minimum wage, we need to learn the lessons it
provides about what is possible. Progress on minimum standards
beyond pay certainly is – most similar economies already manage
it. But we need to think about this in the context of our overall
Low Pay Britain 2023 | Executive Summary 13
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
economic strategy, and about how that can provide more good
jobs. A package of reforms which is grounded in that big-picture
view of the nature of the UK economy and the challenges it faces
means it is not just about improving work for low earners, but
about all of us living in a better and less unequal country.
Low Pay Britain 2023 | Executive Summary 14
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
15
Introduction
Improving low-paid work should be central to the
UK’s economic strategy
Our two-year Economy 2030 Inquiry, a partnership with the Centre for Economic
Performance at the London School of Economics, is investigating how the UK can
make a success of the 2020s, and what kind of economic strategy is needed to tackle
the UK’s twin problems of low growth and high inequality.
1
In this report we focus
on how labour market regulation can not only improve the quality of work, but also
contribute to a transformation in the economic structure of the United Kingdom, and
in so doing contribute to the broader objectives of reducing inequality and raising
living standards.
Raising minimum standards in the labour market offers a chance to
improve the quality of work, but could also change the shape of the
economy
Discussions around labour market regulation have tended to focus on the micro effects
of those policies: in minimum wage policy, for example, we tend to weigh up the wage
benefits to workers against potential negative effects on employment. Of course,
these do matter, and we will discuss the trade-offs involved in policy areas such as the
minimum wage and sick pay later in this report. But we should also look at labour market
policy through a broader lens, because it has the potential to shape the nature of our
economy, and this has been largely absent from the policy discussion around labour
market policy in the UK.
1 For more information, see: https://economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org/.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
16
In big-picture terms, while we should worry about micro-level trade-offs involved in
different areas of labour market policy, we should embrace or at least accept the macro-
level effects that raising minimum standards in the labour market would bring. Along
with improving the quality of work on offer to low-paid workers, raising minimum pay and
conditions would also raise the cost of employing low-paid workers. In sectors where low-
paid workers constitute a significant share of overall costs (such as retail and hospitality)
and where the final product is sold in the UK rather than overseas (meaning it is easier
to raise prices), this would be expected to have a knock-on impact on the relative price
of those goods and services produced by that sector. In turn, and to the extent that
consumption of those items is price-sensitive, we might expect consumption and output
to fall in those sectors. Of course, for a low-paying sector like care which is primarily
funded by the public sector, the effect of higher employment costs would be felt through
public spending and taxation rather than through consumption and output.
Of course, we shouldn’t be blasé about these kinds of changes, and the micro effects
do matter. Big sectoral shifts would be concerning if they affected the employment
prospects of the people working in those sectors (although this needn’t be the case – the
pace of change would likely be slow).
2
But the reason for setting this out is to be clear
that these potential effects are the likely cost of ensuring all workers can enjoy dignity
and security at work.
Moreover, it’s striking that some personal services are currently relatively cheap in the
UK compared to other things we consume, and, perhaps as a result, they comprise a
large share of our consumption. If this was to change, the UK would be becoming more
similar to other European countries. Figure 1 plots the share of residents’ consumption
accounted for by hotels and restaurants across European countries, along with the price
of hotels and restaurants relative to other goods and services consumed within the
country. The UK stands out compared to many other European countries for its relatively
cheap hotels and restaurants, and the large share of our spending which goes on them.
If higher labour market standards led to higher relative prices and less consumption of
hospitality, the UK might become more similar to other European countries (i.e. move
closer to the middle of Figure 1).
2 N Cominetti et al., Changing jobs?: Change in the UK labour market and the role of worker mobility, Resolution Foundation,
January 2022.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
17
FIGURE 1: Hospitality is relatively cheap in the UK, and we consume a lot of it
Hotels and restaurants: share of consumption by residents (2015), and price of relative
to other goods and services within economy (2019): EU countries
SOURCE: Analysis of Eurostat.
Another reason to embrace higher labour market standards is the clear distributional
impact. Workers in low-income households stand to benefit most from raising pay
and conditions in personal service sectors because that is where their employment
is concentrated. On the other hand, if such measures increased the price of those
services (which they very plausibly would), it would be richer households who would
be most affected – because personal services form a larger share of richer households
spending. This relationship is shown in Figure 2, which plots the share of consumption
and employment accounted for by the retail, leisure and hospitality sectors, for
each household income quintile. Those services account for just under a quarter of
consumption and employment for the poorest households (24 per cent and 23 per cent
respectively), while they account for a third (35 per cent) of consumption and less than
a tenth (9 per cent) of employment for the richest households. This means that raising
standards in those sectors would be desirable from a distributional perspective.
Belgium
Bulgaria
Czechia
DenmarkGermany
Estonia
Ireland
Greece
Spain
France
Croatia
Italy
Cyprus
Latvia
Lithuania
Luxembourg
Hungary
Malta
Netherlands
Austria
Poland
Portugal
Romania
Slovenia
Slovakia
Finland
Sweden
Norway
United Kingdom
Montenegro
North Macedonia
Serbia
Türkiye
0%
4%
8%
12%
0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4
Share of
consumption
Price relative to other goods and services in country
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
18
FIGURE 2: Better pay and conditions in non-tradeable services would benefit
low income households, while any price effects would be mainly felt by higher-
income households
Retail, leisure and hospitality as a share of consumption and employment, by after-
housing-costs income quintile: UK, 2019-20
SOURCE: Analysis of ONS, Living Costs and Food Survey; DWP, Family Resources Survey.
We need to focus on improving the jobs we have rather than hoping
for new ones
Another high-level point worth making is that efforts to improve low-paid work must
focus on improving the jobs we have in the UK today, rather than hoping for new and
‘better’ types of jobs to emerge which will solve the problem for us. Low-paid work in the
UK is predominantly made up of jobs in private-sector non-tradeable services of various
kinds, which account for 1.5 million out of 2.5 million low-paid jobs (defined as earning
below two thirds of the hourly median wage).
3
While new forms of work will continue
to emerge, history tells us that these types of service jobs aren’t going anywhere. For
the economy as a whole, private non-tradeable services (including retail, bars and
restaurants, care, and other personal services) account for a similar share of employment
today (10.8 million jobs, 34 per cent of the total) as they did thirty years ago (in 1992 these
figures were 33 per cent and 7.8 million jobs).
4
And while the net zero transition and
3 Source: RF analysis of ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings (2022). Non-tradeable private-sector services here excludes
public services apart from social care. It covers the following Standard Industrial Classification divisions: 45 Vehicle sales &
repaid, 47 Retail trade, 49 Land transport, 53 Postal activities, 56 Food and beverage services, 68 Real estate, 75 Veterinary
activities, 77 Renting and leasing services, 79 Travel agencies, 80 Security and investigation, 87-88 Social care, 90 Creative, arts and
entertainment, 91 Libraries, archives, museums and other cultural activities, 93 Sports activities and amusement and recreation
activities, 94 Activities of membership organisations, 96 Other personal service activities. This list is largely based on that
developed by B Broadbent et al., The Brexit Vote, Productivity Growth and Macroeconomic Adjustments in the United Kingdom,
mimeo., 2020, apart from the removal of public services apart from social care, and the inclusion of food and beverage services.
4 Source: RF analysis of ONS, Workforce Jobs. Sectors included are as listed in the previous footnote.
24%
26%
30%
32%
35%
23%
20%
17%
14%
9%
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
Lowest income
quintile
Quintile 2 Quintile 3 Quintile 4 Highest income
quintile
Consumption Employment
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
19
perhaps the adoption of new technology could give fresh impetus to structural change,
again history tells us to be cautious. The pace of change in terms of the sectors we work
in has actually been slowing down rather than speeding up since the 1980s, when the big
shift from manufacturing to services took place.
5
Another reason for focusing on these jobs is that there are many parts of the country
which are especially reliant on them. Figure 3 plots the median hourly pay and the share
of jobs in non-tradeable services (excluding the public sector) for each local labour
market (proxied by 218 travel-to-work areas). That there are many local areas where pay
is low, and where the share of jobs in non-tradeable services is well above the national
average (this applies to all areas shown in the bottom right quadrant of the chart). In
some coastal and rural towns these sectors account for around 1 in 2 jobs, including
places such as Sidmouth (59 per cent of al jobs), Penzance (53 per cent), and Whitby
(50 per cent). In these places a radical shift in industrial structure is even less likely than
it is at the national level. The country is too small to have ‘global cities’ in every region,
despite what the Levelling Up White Paper said.
6
If we are serious about good work being
available in all parts of the country, then we need to focus on measures which will make a
difference to workers in these jobs, many of which are concentrated in the poorest parts
of the country.
5 N Cominetti et al., Changing jobs?: Change in the UK labour market and the role of worker mobility, Resolution Foundation,
January 2022.
6 Department for Levelling Up, Housing and Communities, Levelling Up the United Kingdom, February 2022.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
20
FIGURE 3: The goal of good work being available everywhere means using
minimum standards to improve all jobs, especially in non-tradeable services
Median hourly pay (2022) and share of jobs in non-tradeable services excluding the
public sector (2021), by travel to work area: GB
NOTES: Bubble size represents total jobs in travel to work area. Area refers to location of workplace.
Non-tradeable private-sector services here excludes public services apart from social care. It covers the
following Standard Industrial Classification divisions: 45 Vehicle sales & repaid, 47 Retail trade, 49 Land
transport, 53 Postal activities, 56 Food and beverage services, 68 Real estate, 75 Veterinary activities,
77 Renting and leasing services, 79 Travel agencies, 80 Security and investigation, 87-88 Social care, 90
Creative, arts and entertainment, 91 Libraries, archives, museums and other cultural activities, 93 Sports
activities and amusement and recreation activities, 94 Activities of membership organisations, 96 Other
personal service activities. This list is largely based on that developed by B Broadbent et al., The Brexit Vote,
Productivity Growth and Macroeconomic Adjustments in the United Kingdom, mimeo., 2020, apart from
the removal of public services apart from social care, and the inclusion of food and beverage services.
SOURCE: Analysis of ONS, Business Register and Employment Survey; ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and
Earnings (both via Nomis).
The rest of this report is organised as follows.
Section 2 presents some measures of ‘good work, and how this varies for high and
low-paid workers.
Section 3 shows that when it comes to pay, the UK has a high (and rising) floor, and
this has hugely reduced hourly pay inequality.
Section 4, by contrast, shows that this is not the case for the floor when it comes
to conditions and protections, where the UK has a very low level compared to other
countries.
Section 5 sets out a set of policy options for improving pay and conditions.
Section 6 concludes.
Whitby
Bury St Edmunds
London
Milton Keynes
Oxford
Reading
Kingsbridge and Dartmouth
Penzance
Sidmouth
Weston-super-Mare
Ayr
£10
£15
£20
20% 30% 40% 50% 60%
Median
hourly
pay
Share of jobs in private sector
non-tradeable services
GB
GB
Areas with low pay & large
share of jobs in private sector
non-tradeable services
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
21
Section 2
The uneven distribution of ‘good’ work
Focusing on the quality, not just quantity, of work should be at the heart of any
modern economic strategy. Quality work matters for our well-being and happiness:
twice the share of workers with insecure working hours report that work makes them
feel miserable when compared to workers that have secure hours (11 per cent versus
5 per cent). And ‘bad’ elements of work tend to most concentrated in some personal
service jobs (such as administrative occupations, elementary sales and for drivers).
There is an unequal distribution of ‘quality’ work (which includes both aspects that
are amenable to policy and those of a more subjective nature) when it comes to how
much workers are paid. Survey evidence shows that over half (56 per cent) of workers
with a gross individual income below £20,000 expect not to be paid if they had to
miss a day of work because of a family emergency, compared to one-in-ten (12 per
cent) of workers with incomes over £60,000. A range of other ‘bad’ work attributes
are particularly concentrated on the lowest paid workers, including four-in-ten (38
per cent) of employees in the lowest-paid quintile expressing they have “little or
no autonomy over the tasks they do at work”. Finally, insecure work and a lack of
autonomy or satisfaction with work is concentrated among Black, disabled and young
workers.
Focusing on the quality, not just quantity, of work should be at the heart of any modern
economic strategy. This Section sets out evidence on the inequalities that exist between
workers when it comes to the quality of work. In particular, we focus on contract or hours
insecurity and the regularity of hours worked – aspects of work that can be regulated.
We also draw attention to some of the more subjective attitudes towards work – namely,
job satisfaction and feeling of autonomy at work. In doing so we build the argument that
good work should be in all pockets of the labour force: everyone deserves a decent wage
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
22
and to be treated with dignity at work. And work should be fulfilling – after all, most of us
spend a large share of our waking hours at work. In later Sections of this report we turn to
the specifics of what can and should be done to raise minimum labour market standards.
Quality work matters for well-being
First off, we should care about good quality work because it matters for workers’ lives
and well-being. Working with high intensity, for example – something that has risen in the
UK
7
– increases the likelihood of people reporting stress, depression and burnout.
8
The
reverse is true for more ‘positive’ aspects of work: levels of overall well-being tend to be
particularly high for workers who feel they have autonomy over tasks at work or where
there are opportunities for progression.
9
Certain forms of insecure work – which are a big part of 21st century life for the lowest-
paid workers – can have pernicious effects on our well-being and happiness.
10
For
example, twice the share of workers with insecure working hours report that work makes
them feel miserable than among workers that have secure hours (11 per cent versus 5 per
cent).
11
And one-in-five (20 per cent) of those workers on insecure hours also report work
makes them feel uneasy, compared to one-in-ten (9 per cent of) workers with secure
hours of work. This evidence provides reason to believe that giving workers more security
in some parts of their job, specifically secure working hours, might improve these
workers’ well-being.
12
‘Bad’ work characteristics are concentrated in certain jobs
A second related reason as to why we should focus on job quality is that jobs tend to
be ‘bad’ in more than one way. As Figure 4 shows, occupations with a high share of
workers on insecure contracts or where hours and pay vary (i.e. insecure hours) also tend
to be those where employees report little or no autonomy over tasks at work. This is
particularly apparent for some service jobs – such as administrative occupations, where
56 per cent of employees have little or no autonomy over tasks at work and 24 per cent
experience contract or hours insecurity.
7 K Shah & D Tomlinson, Work experiences: Changes in the subjective experience of work, The Economy 2030 Inquiry, May 2021.
8 T Hunt & H Pickard, Harder, better, faster, stronger? Work intensity and ‘good work’ in the United Kingdom, Industrial Relations
Journal 53(3), April 2022.
9 Analysis of ONS, Annual Population Survey.
10 Contract insecurity, hours or pay volatility and hours insufficiency are most concentrated on the lowest paid workers, for example.
See: N Cominetti et al. Low Pay Britain 2022: Low pay and insecurity in the UK labour market, Resolution Foundation, May 2022.
11 Analysis of UK Skills & Employment Survey, 2017.
12 A Felstead et al., Unpredictable times: the extent, characteristics and correlates of insecure hours of work in Britain, Industrial
Relations Journal 51(1-2), January 2020.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
23
FIGURE 4: Jobs tend to be ‘bad’ in more than one way – particularly among
some personal service occupations
Proportion of employees with little or no autonomy over tasks at work compared to
those on an insecure contract or where hours and pay vary, by occupation: UK
NOTES: Each circle represents one occupation, measured at the three-digit SOC level. Size of circle
represents
average number of workers in the occupation in 2020-2022. Includes employees only. Autonomy questions
in Understanding Society are only asked every other wave, so these figures pool the latest three years of
available data in each survey.
SOURCE: Analysis of UK Household Longitudinal Study (Understanding Society); UK Skills & Employment
Survey; ONS, Labour Force Survey.
This is by no means a perfect relationship. A very high share of carers (30 per cent), for
example, are on insecure contracts or volatile hours – but a more modest share of this
group feel that they have little or no autonomy over tasks at work (26 per cent).
13
The
reverse is true for customer service occupations, where around 13 per cent of employees
have insecure contracts or hours but nearly half of employees (46 per cent) feel they
have little or no autonomy over tasks at work.
This result extends previous Economy 2030 work showing that some (low-paid) personal
service occupations experience high levels of both contract or hours insecurity and
hours insufficiency.
14
At a minimum, workers deserve the dignity and respect that control
over hours and contracts provide. But we should place equal weight on the sense of
workplace autonomy, which is highly prized by workers and – given the relationship
highlighted in Figure 4 – may even be influenced by the incidence of insecure work.
13 For further discussion of working conditions in this sector – and the nuances around the subjective experiences of social care
workers – see: N Cominetti, Who cares?: The experience of social care workers, and the enforcement of employment rights in the
sector, Resolution Foundation, January 2023.
14 K Shah & D Tomlinson, Work experiences: Changes in the subjective experience of work, September 2021.
Nurses & midwives
Teachers
Health associates
Sports & fitness
Food prep & hospitality
Childcare
Carers
Leisure & travel
Cleaners
Sales & retail assistants
Customer service
Drivers
Administrators
Elementary sales
Other service occupations
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70%
Share of employees with little or no autonomy over tasks at work, 2016-2022
Share of employees on insecure contract or volatile hours,
2020-2022
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
24
Having set out our reasons for focusing on job quality, we next turn to the experience
of job quality across groups of workers and in different parts of the country. But before
turning to the distribution of quality work, we need to be clear that there is no single
definition of what constitutes a ‘good’ or ‘quality’ job.
15
There are, however, a series of
domains and aspects which we believe need to be viewed in the round to understand the
quality of work (see Box 1).
15 Some organisations have sought to create an overall measure of job quality. See, for example: Lumina Foundation, Gates
Foundation and Omidyar Network Tell Full Story of U.S. Job Quality, Gallup. In the UK, the ONS has in the past provided a
composite measure of ‘job quality’ consisting of having a desired contract, satisfactory hours and not being in low pay – although
the ONS itself recognises that this measure does not provide a complete picture of ‘job quality’. See: ONS, Job quality indicators in
the UK – hours, pay and contracts: 2018, December 2019.
16 The Measuring Good Work final report recommended existing and new survey questions that could be used to assess “quality
employment”. To fill the existing data gap the ONS has incorporated more job quality indicators into its Annual Population Survey
(APS)/Labour Force Survey (LFS). See: G Irvine, D White & M Diffley, Measuring Good Work: The final report of the Measuring Job
Quality Working Group, The Carnergie UK Trust & Royal Society of Arts, September 2018.
BOX 1: ‘Good’ work can be defined in many ways
To assess the quality of work, we
need to be able to measure a range
of job quality measures.
16
Combining
questions from the Annual Population
Survey (APS)/Labour Force Survey
(LFS) with measures from the UK Skills
and Employment Survey (UKSES) and
the UK Household Longitudinal Study
(Understanding Society) it is possible to
create a holistic picture of job quality in
the UK (see Figure 5).
There are large differences in the share
of employees reporting they have these
different elements of job quality. The
features of job quality reported by the
highest share of employees are having
a desired contract (99 per cent), being
satisfied with their manager (85 per
cent) and satisfied with training (69 per
cent). Some features like agency work
or being on a ZHC are only experienced
by a relatively small share of employees
(around 3 per cent for both).
Some of the elements of job quality
experienced by employees are more
amenable to policy, for example,
contract or hours security, low hourly
pay and holiday pay entitlements. Other
elements might be considered less
amenable to policy such as different
measures of satisfaction or some of the
‘bad’ elements of work like feeling tense,
depressed or anxious. These aspects
are perhaps more difficult to regulate
but this does not mean they are any
less important.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
25
FIGURE 5: There are lots of different elements that determine the quality of
work
Proportion of employees reporting that their job has feature of different measures of
job quality: UK/GB, 2017-2022
NOTES: Each measure provides the latest year available from the dataset used.
SOURCE: Analysis of British Household Panel Survey; UK Household Longitudinal Study (Understanding
Society); UK Skills & Employment Survey; ONS, Labour Force Survey; ONS, Annual Population Survey;
BEIS, Trade Union Membership Statistics.
17 Analysis of UKSES.
18 M Williams, Y Zhou & M Zou, Mapping Good Work: The Quality of Working Life Across the Occupational Structure, Bristol
University Press, September 2020.
The literature suggests that workers
place different values on the indicators
in Figure 5 – and the overall quality
of work. The simplest way to glean
this information is to ask workers
directly what they value. For example,
the UKSES asks workers “what is the
main attraction of your current job”?
For over a third of respondents in the
latest wave (2018-2020) the response is
either “better money” (20 per cent) or
“better career prospects” (15 per cent).
17
Another way of measuring job quality
is to look at the relationship between
different indicators and overall job
satisfaction. UK research suggests that
job security and how much you like
work explains much of the differences
in job satisfaction.
18
Finally, workers
might also be willing to trade-off pay
to enjoy other benefits at work; for
example, US-based work finds that
0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
Desired contract
Hours vary
Anxious about hours
Hours vary (and paid hourly)
Underemployed
Temp worker
ZHC
Agency worker
Part-time (can't find FT)
Temp (don't want perm.)
Temp (can't find perm.)
Satisfied with pay
Low weekly pay
Low hourly pay
Satisfied with manager
Satisfied with training
Overall job satisfaction
Job offers progression opp.
Autonomy over tasks
Tense at work
Depressed at work
Homeworking
Flexi-time
Termtime sharing
No holiday pay
Overemployed
Involved in decision-making
TU membership
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
26
workers at Walmart would forgo wages
for more “dignity at work
19
and that
non-pay amenities (like days of annual
leave) offer a wage premium.
20
Some of the indicators detailed in
Figure 5 will matter more or less
depending on who you are and what job
you work in. For example, there are clear
gender differences. In wave 14 of the
British Household Panel Survey (BHPS)
women placed a higher importance
on “the nature of work” than men.
This finding holds across a range of
European countries and women are
19 A Dube, S Naidu & A Reich, Power and Dignity in the Low-Wage Labor Market: Theory and Evidence from Wal-Mart Workers, NBER,
Working Paper 30441, September 2022.
20 N Maestas et al. The Value of Working Conditions in the United States and Implications for the Structure of Wages, NBER, Working
Paper 25204, October 2018.
21 P Redmon & S McGuinnes, Explaining the Gender Gap in Job Satisfaction, IZA Discussion Paper 12703, October 2019.
22 https://www.gov.uk/time-off-for-dependants, accessed 5 April 2023.
also found to place greater importance
on work-life balance than men.
21
Overall, there are a range of job quality
measures we should care about. Pay
clearly matters but it is not the whole
story (particularly given workers are
willing to trade-off their wages for
other benefits). In this report we
present a range of indicators including
pay, contract and hours security,
job satisfaction, autonomy at work,
flexibility and opportunities for career
progression.
Large inequalities exist when it comes to ‘quality’ work – for example
on flexible working arrangements
As already discussed (see Box 1), workers value the non-pay aspects of work – some
of which workers have rights to (like holiday and sick leave) and other aspects they
do not (like working from home). Next, we show that the degree of flexibility provided
to employees by their employers differs across groups. How employees expect their
employers to respond if they needed to attend a family emergency, for example, is not
consistent across the income distribution (see Figure 6). As an employee one is legally
allowed to take time off to deal with an emergency involving a dependent.
22
But over half
(56 per cent) of workers with a gross individual income less than £20,000 expect not to be
paid if they missed a day of work for this reason compared to just one-in-ten (12 per cent)
of workers with incomes over £60,000. By contrast, eight-in-ten (81 per cent) of workers
earning above £60,000 said they would expect to be paid as normal. Just three-in-ten
(29 per cent) of the lowest paid workers would expect to miss a day and be paid. So,
most workers expect to be able to miss a day in the case of an emergency but the lowest
income workers are least likely to receive some form of remuneration for time off.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
27
FIGURE 6: Big inequalities exist on flexible working arrangements
Proportion of private-sector employees reporting how their employer would respond if
they needed to attend a family emergency, by gross individual income band: UK, 10-14
March 2023
NOTES: Base is all private-sector employees (n=2011). All also includes those who didn’t give an income
figure. Under £20,000 (n=330), £20,000-£29,999 (n=477), £30,000-£39,999 (n=340), £40,000-£49,000 (n=238),
£50,000-£59,000 (n=144) and £60,000 plus (n=223).
SOURCE: Analysis of YouGov, March 2023 survey.
Thirty years ago, low-paid workers enjoyed a job satisfaction
premium – that’s largely gone
To assess quality work, it is important to understand the subjective value workers place
on work in and of itself. Most straightforwardly, this means looking at trends in overall job
satisfaction. Figure 7 plots the proportion of employees who report that they are either
‘mostly’ or ‘completely’ satisfied with their present job in 1991-1993 and 2020-2022. The
most striking feature of the last three decades is that the satisfaction premium enjoyed
by low-paid workers has virtually disappeared. In the early 1990s, around 76 per cent of
workers in the lowest paid quintile were “mostly” or “completely” satisfied with their jobs
compared to around 60 per cent of the highest paid workers. Fast forward to 2020-2022
and the rates of job satisfaction for the lowest (62 per cent) and highest (63 per cent)
paid workers look remarkably similar. As previous Economy 2030 work has highlighted,
this is a story of low earners having lost their satisfaction premium rather than having
fallen behind the rest – which means that some of the non-pay benefits for the lowest
paid have disappeared over time.
23
This is consistent with low-paid work having become
more stressful and intense.
23 D Tomlinson & K Shah, https://economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org/reports/work-experiences/, Resolution Foundation,
September 2021; A Clark et al., The true returns to the choice of occupation and education, Centre for Economic Performance,
February 2021.
56%
38%
25%
19%
17%
12%
32%
29%
47%
60%
70%
67%
81%
55%
14%
13%
13%
11%
15%
7%
13%
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100%
Under £20,000
£20,000-£29,999
£30,000-£39,999
£40,000-£49,999
£50,000-£59,999
£60,000 plus
All
Refuse to let me miss work Miss a day but not paid Miss a day and be paid Other/ don’t know
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
28
FIGURE 7: The low paid job satisfaction premium has disappeared
Proportion of employees who are “mostly” or “completely” satisfied with their present
job overall, employees by monthly earnings quintile: GB/UK
SOURCE: Analysis of British Household Panel Survey; UK Household Longitudinal Study (Understanding
Society).
Markers of ‘bad’ work are found in all types of jobs - but are
experienced most by low earners
Next, we turn to a range of ‘bad’ aspects of work and where they are most concentrated.
We find that examples of ‘bad’ quality work are found everywhere. As Figure 8 highlights
28 per cent of workers either feel they have “little or no autonomy over the tasks they do
at work” or that they are “not satisfied with their job. Focusing on specific occupations
with the highest share of employees who are “not satisfied with their job” there is a
real mix, including elementary sales (39 per cent), legal professionals (38 per cent),
elementary administrators (38 per cent) and IT technicians (37 per cent). Even some
jobs that we might traditionally identify as ‘good’ (perhaps in terms of pay level or hours
security) might therefore have ‘bad’ characteristics.
24
Having said this, a range of ‘bad’ work attributes are particularly concentrated among the
lowest paid workers - with 38 per cent of employees in the lowest paid quintile expressing
they have ‘little or no autonomy over the tasks they do at work’. This is less of a surprise
when we consider that most occupations with little or no autonomy (see Figure 4) tend
to be lower paid. The right-hand panel of Figure 8 underlines how insecure contracts or
volatile hours and hours insufficiency are much more prevalent among low earners than
high earners. We have previously explored the direct impact of this on wellbeing – in
24 S O’Connor, It is possible to hate your job but love your work, Financial Times, February 2023.
76%
60%
60%
55%
60%
62%
55%
57%
58%
63%
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
Quintile 1
(lowest paid)
Quintile 2 Quintile 3 Quintile 4 Quintile 5
(highest paid)
1991-1993 2020-2022
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
29
2017, 36 per cent of employees in the bottom hourly pay quintile said they are anxious
about unexpected changes in their hours of work (amounting to 2 million workers, out
of a total of 7.2 million workers across all pay level who report this anxiety).
25
Crucially,
the UK currently has no system in place for offering protection against this. Introducing
minimum standards in these areas would therefore improve the quality of work in the UK
especially for the lowest paid workers.
26
FIGURE 8: Examples of ‘bad’ work are found everywhere – but are most
concentrated among low paying jobs
Proportion of employees reporting that their job has feature of selected measure of job
quality, hourly pay quintile: UK, 2020-2022/2022
NOTES: ‘Insecure contract or volatile hours’ includes workers who: are paid hourly and hours vary; are
on a temporary contract involuntarily; agency workers; and workers on a zero-hours contract. ‘Hours
insufficiency’ includes workers who want to work more hours; who are working part-time and would prefer
to work full-time; or who are looking for a new job for reason of wanting to work more hours. Measures
were first used in: N Cominetti et al. Low Pay Britain 2022: Low pay and insecurity in the UK labour market,
Resolution Foundation, May 2022.
SOURCE: Autonomy and job satisfaction from analysis of UK Household Longitudinal Study
(Understanding Society) (2020-2022); Insecure contract / volatile hours & hours insufficiency are from
analysis of ONS, Labour Force Survey (2022).
Insecure work and a lack of autonomy or satisfaction with work is
concentrated among black, disabled and young workers
We next turn to the distribution of quality work across different demographic groups.
Again, we focus on not being satisfied with your job, feeling little or no autonomy over
tasks at work, having insufficient hours and workers who are on insecure contracts or
25 N Cominetti, C McCurdy & H Slaughter, Low Pay Britain 2021, June 2021.
26 T Bell, N Cominetti & H Slaughter, A new settlement for the low paid: Beyond the minimum wage to dignity and respect, Resolution
Foundation, June 2020.
28%
38%
34%
30%
23%
15%
28%
29%
30%
29%
29%
28%
0% 20% 40%
All
Lowest paid
Quintile 2
Quintile 3
Quintile 4
Highest paid
Little or no autonomy
Not satisfied with job
13%
22%
16%
12%
9%
6%
9%
17%
11%
7%
5%
4%
0% 10% 20% 30%
All
Lowest paid
Quintile 2
Quintile 3
Quintile 4
Highest paid
Insecure contract or volatile hours
Hours insufficiency
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
30
have volatile hours. We have already presented evidence that these elements of poor-
quality work are concentrated among some low paying occupations (like administrators,
elementary sales and services occupations) – and low-paid workers more generally. It
follows that certain demographic groups who are over-represented in low paid jobs will
be most likely to experience these negative sides to work. We can see from Figure 9 that
insecure work (including hours insufficiency and insecure contracts/ volatile hours) and a
lack autonomy or satisfaction at work is concentrated among young, black and disabled
workers. The proportion of black workers on insecure contracts/volatile hours or with
insufficient hours is almost twice that of white workers (22 per cent versus 13 per cent
and 13 per cent versus 8 per cent, respectively). In a similar vein, 34 per cent of disabled
workers are not satisfied with their job compared to only 28 per cent of non-disabled
workers.
FIGURE 9: Insecure work and a lack of autonomy or satisfaction is
concentrated among black, disabled and young workers
Proportion of employees reporting that their job has feature of selected measure of job
quality, demographic groups: UK, 2020-2022/2022
NOTES: See notes in Figure 8 for a description of the measures used.
SOURCE: Autonomy and job satisfaction from analysis of UK Household Longitudinal Study
(Understanding Society) (2020-2022); Insecure contract / volatile hours & hours insufficiency are from
analysis of ONS, Labour Force Survey (2022).
The differences we observe between demographic groups will be determined by job,
rather than personal, characteristics. We can formalise this line of thought by running a
dominance” analysis (which runs every possible combination of a regression model and
determines the relative importance of independent variables in explaining the variation
0% 20% 40%
All
18-29
30-49
50-64
65+
Men
Women
Black
White
Mixed
Asian
Disabled
Non-disabled
Not satisfied with job Little or no autonomy
0% 10% 20% 30%
All
18-29
30-49
50-64
65+
Men
Women
Black
White
Mixed
Asian
Disabled
Non-disabled
Hours insufficiency
Insecure contract or volatile hours
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
31
for a dependent variable). Measures of workplace insecurity are most associated with
occupation, pay and sector rather than personal characteristics like ethnicity, disability
status or age.
27
Using a similar approach regression analysis shows that differences in
whether someone is not satisfied with their job or feels little or no autonomy over tasks
at work are almost entirely explained by their occupation – and to a lesser extent their
pay. In other words, being serious about job quality means raising standards at the level
of the job.
28
There are large geographic differences in unfavourable job
characteristics
Finally, we highlight that large geographic differences exist when it comes to
unfavourable job characteristics. We show that this is the case in Figure 10, which charts
the share of employees with not good employee involvement in decisions made at the
workplace (horizontal axis) and where employees feel there is no good opportunities for
progression in their job (vertical axis) - at the local authority level. Over half of employees
have no good opportunities for progression in the likes of Dudley (56 per cent),
Sunderland (56 per cent), Barnsley (55 per cent) and Wolverhampton (55 per cent). This
is around twice the rate of London boroughs like Barking and Dagenham (29 per cent),
Islington (28 per cent) and Tower Hamlets (28 per cent). These geographic trends will
be driven by the industrial make-up of different local labour markets. For example, there
is a disproportionate share of employees working in professional services (particularly
finance) in the capital – in which workers report the highest perceived progression
opportunities.
29
27 N Cominetti et al., Low Pay Britain 2022, Low pay and insecurity in the UK labour market, Resolution Foundation, May 2022.
28 Analysis of UK Household Longitudinal Study (Understanding Society).
29 Office for National Statistics, Job quality in the UK – analysis of job quality indicators: 2021, December 2022.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
32
FIGURE 10: There are large geographic differences in unfavourable job
characteristics
Proportion of employees who express not good employee involvement in decisions
made at work and no good opportunities for career progression, local authorities: 2021
SOURCE: Analysis of ONS, Annual Population Survey.
Overall, we would like more people to have a positive experience at work, to have the
opportunity to find good work, and to remove the worst aspects of work. Low-paid
workers deserve particular attention – given that they have little say at work when
it comes to things like the regularity of hours, shift patterns and flexible working
arrangements. As we have shown in this section there are many aspects of quality work
that cannot be directly regulated for – such as job satisfaction, autonomy at work and
opportunities for progression. But there are some elements of work we can regulate for –
and that is what the rest of the paper focuses on.
Barking and Dagenham
Camden
Islington
Lambeth
Tower Hamlets
Barnsley
Sunderland
Birmingham
Coventry
Dudley
Wolverhampton
Brighton and Hove
Powys
Ceredigion
Merthyr Tydfill
Dumfries & Galloway
Midlothian
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70%
Lack good
opportunities
for career
progression
Lack good employee involvement
in workplace decision-making
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
33
Section 3
The impact of a rising minimum wage
The improvements made to the minimum wage in recent years have transformed
the low pay landscape in the UK. Since 2016 and the introduction of the National
Living Wage the minimum wage has been lifted rapidly the UK’s minimum wage is
now among the highest in the world – currently the only countries which are similarly
rich to the UK with higher minimum wages (relative to median pay among full-time
workers in those countries) are France, New Zealand and Korea.
Raising the wage floor has hugely reduced hourly pay inequality. The proportion of
employees in ‘low’ hourly pay (earning below two-thirds of the median) fell to 9 per
cent in 2022 (2.5 million workers), by far the lowest since our data series begins in the
late 1960s, and down from 21 per cent in 2015 (5.5 million workers). It has also changed
the shape of pay growth – in the 1980s and 1990s the highest earners saw the fastest
pay growth and the lowest earners the slowest, and this pattern has been reversed in
the minimum wage era.
We showed in the last section that good work is highly unequally distributed, and noted
that some dimensions of what makes work good can be improved by setting minimum
standards. In the next two sections we describe where the UK currently stands when
it comes to minimum standards on pay (this section) and conditions and non-pay
amenities (the following section). The contrast is clear. The UK has made tremendous
progress on low pay thanks to an ambitious minimum wage policy, which has pushed the
UK’s wage floor to among the highest in the world. This has hugely benefited low-paid
workers. By contrast, the next section will show that the UK has low minimum standards
compared to other rich countries when it comes to sick pay, parental pay and holiday
entitlement, and has done little to address pay and hours insecurity.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
34
Hourly pay inequality, and the proportion of workers in ‘low pay’ is at
a record low, thanks to big increases in the minimum wage
The introduction of the National Living Wage in 2015 (a higher minimum wage for
employees aged 25 and above – extended in 2021 to workers age 23 and above) and its
subsequent fast uprating have had a significant impact on the wages of low-paid workers.
On a number of measures, the proportion of workers who are low paid is at its lowest
ever level. These measures are set out in Figure 11.
The most commonly used measure of ‘low pay’ is a relative one – the proportion of
workers whose hourly pay is below two-thirds of the median (the red line in Figure 11). On
this headline measure, 9.0 per cent of employees in 2022 (totalling 2.5 million) were low
paid, which is less than half the rate of 2015 (20.7 per cent, totalling 5.5 million). It is not
surprising that this headline low pay measure is now low. Median hourly pay in 2022 was
£14.72, putting the low pay threshold for this measure at £9.81, just 41p above £9.50, the
level of the National Living Wage in 2022.
This recent rapid fall in the proportion of workers in low pay is the more remarkable for
coming after a twenty-year period in which there was very little change. The low pay rate
was not very different in 2015 (20.7 per cent) than it was in 1998 (22.6 per cent), the year
before the minimum wage was introduced. In its early years the minimum wage was
lower, and uprated relatively cautiously. This eroded the number of workers in ‘extreme
low pay’ (earning less than half of the median - the light green line in Figure 11) from 7.0
per cent in 1998 to 2.2 per cent by 2006, since then this rate has been relatively steady.
But it took the faster uprating of the National Living Wage era (from 2016 onwards) to
bring down the number of workers in ‘low’ pay on the headline measure.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
35
FIGURE 11: The proportion of workers in low pay has fallen dramatically since
2015, while the number of workers earning the minimum wage has been stable
Proportion of employees in different measures of low hourly pay: GB
NOTES:At or below minimum wage’ defined as earning below the age-specific minimum wage plus 5p.
SOURCE: Analysis of ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings and New Earnings Survey Panel Dataset.
Another important way of measuring ‘low pay’ is the proportion of workers earning below
the real Living Wage – the hourly wage rate calculated by the Living Wage Foundation,
based on what someone working full-time needs to earn to be able to afford a minimally
acceptable basket of goods and services. In April 2022, the real Living Wage was £9.90 in
the UK (and £11.05 in London) and 13.4 per cent of workers were earning below this level.
As with the headline low pay rate, this again is the lowest on record.
An encouraging aspect of this period of falling low pay coming from a rising minimum
wage has been that the number of workers on the minimum wage has been steady. One
of the concerns raised in 2015 when the National Living Wage was announced was that
a higher minimum wage would lead to an ever-growing number of workers bunched on
the wage floor.
30
This might have negative implications for workers’ incentives to progress
to better paid jobs, and could pose problems for firms’ pay structures. But this hasn’t
happened. The number of workers at or below the wage floor rose did rise by 300,000 in
2016 (to 1.8 million, 6.9 per cent of employees) but has since been relatively stable, and
in fact in the most recent 2022 data the number of workers on the wage floor fell to 1.7
million (6.0 per cent of employees). We showed in last years Low Pay Britain report
30 L Gardiner & A Corlett, Low Pay Britain 2015, October 2015.
Below two-thirds
median
9.0%
Below half median
1.4%
At or below
minimum wage
6.0%
Below minimum wage
3.0%
Below real Living wage
13.4%
0%
10%
20%
30%
1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
36
that this finding (of no additional bunching on the wage floor) holds even in low-paying
sectors like retail and hospitality.
Less positively, the number of workers earning below the age-specific minimum wage has
risen in the latest data, to more than half a million (545,000) employees, comprising 3.0
per cent of all employees. Minimum wage underpayment has been a problem since its
inception, but this level of underpayment is much higher than the level in 2015 (297,000)
before the introduction of the pre-National Living Wage.
31
This suggests that a higher
minimum wage has led to greater non-compliance. This is unsurprising – employers have
more to gain from underpayment when the minimum wage is higher – but it underlines
the greater importance of proper enforcement as our wage floor becomes more
ambitious.
32
The rate of low pay has fallen particularly rapidly for women, and
young workers
The fall in low pay (on the headline measure – hourly pay below two thirds of the median)
has been particularly rapid for those groups of workers who have tended to have below-
average rates of pay, such as women, and younger and older workers. Starting with
gender, there has been a consistent fall in the low hourly pay gap between genders
over the past 50 years. In 1970, almost half (45 per cent) of women earned a ‘low’ rate
of hourly pay, compared to 12 per cent of men – a 33 percentage point gender pay gap.
Twenty years on, in 1990, the rate of low pay among men was the same, but had fallen
to 32 per cent among women, which meant the gender pay gap had come down by a
third, although women were still close to three times as likely to be low paid. In 2022, the
gender low pay gap was just 2.9 percentage points - 10.5 per cent among men and 7.6 per
cent among women. This is set out in the left-hand panel of Figure 12. Finally, and also set
out in Figure 12, low pay has in the National Living Wage era been falling among all age
groups, but particularly rapidly for workers in their 20s.
31 This level of non-compliance is higher because it comes from the Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings, a survey of employers,
who naturally have an incentive to hide any non-compliance. For this reason, the estimates of minimum wage underpayment from
ASHE have tended to be regarded as a lower bound estimate.
32 At the end of April 2023 we will be publishing the conclusion of our three-year review into labour market enforcement, which will
recommend, among other things, tougher penalties for minimum wage non-compliance. For our report on minimum wage non-
compliance, please see: L Judge and A Stansbury, Under the wage floor: Exploring firms’ incentives to comply with the minimum
wage, January 2020.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
37
FIGURE 12: The fall in low pay has been particularly pronounced for women and
young workers
Proportion of employees in low hourly pay (earning below two-thirds of overall median),
by gender and age group: GB
SOURCE: Analysis of ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings and New Earnings Survey Panel Dataset.
The minimum wage has upended the shape of hourly wage growth
in the UK
In the low pay charts above, it’s notable that the rate of low pay (both on the headline
measure – below two-thirds of median hourly pay – but also on the ‘extreme’ low pay
measure – below half of median hourly pay) was rising in the 1980s and 1990s. This was
a period in which hourly pay inequality (along with overall income inequality) increased,
as top earners pulled away from middle and low earners, and middle earners pulled away
from the bottom. Annual hourly real pay growth averaged 3.2 per cent per year across the
top quintile, compared to 2 per cent at the median, and 1.4 per cent across the bottom
quintile.
The introduction of the minimum wage in 1999 completely changed this pattern, driving
stronger real wage growth at the bottom (1.4 per cent per year) than at the middle or top
(0.6 per cent per year). It’s notable that, despite the inversion of the pay growth pattern,
the bottom did similarly in the minimum wage era as they had in the 1980s and 1990s,
such was the scale of the slowdown in overall pay growth.
The National Living Wage era (from 2015) strengthened the bottom-heavy shape of pay
growth. Real pay growth at the median was again 0.6 per cent per year across 2015 to
All
Men
Women
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
1970 1990 2010
Gender
All
30 to 55
21 to 29
56 to 65
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
1970 1990 2010
Age
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
38
2022, but was 2.5 per cent per year across the bottom fifth of earners, and actually fell by
0.3 per cent per year across the top fifth of the pay distribution. These findings are set
out in Figure 13, which plots the rate of real pay growth in annual terms across the pay
distribution over these different periods.
FIGURE 13: The minimum wage completely changed the pattern of wage
growth in favour of low earners
Annualised growth in real hourly pay across the distribution in selected periods: GB
NOTES: Pay adjusted for CPI inflation.
SOURCE: Analysis of ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings and New Earnings Survey Panel Dataset.
With the National Living Wage on a target path to rise to a ‘bite’ of two-thirds of median
pay by 2024, hourly pay growth will continue to be significantly stronger at the bottom
than at the middle. This month (April 2023), the National Living Wage rose to £10.42, a 9.7
per cent cash increase. The OBR expect CPI inflation to be 6.9 per cent in Q2 2023, which
would mean minimum wage earners’ pay will rise 2.6 per cent in real terms. By contrast,
and drawing on the OBR’s forecast again, the growth of average weekly pay is likely now
only just recovering to zero.
33
The UK’s minimum wage is set to be one of the highest in the world
by 2024
The rapid progress on the wage floor made since 2015 has meant that the UK now has
one of the highest minimum wages (relative to median pay) in the world. The OECD
measure the ‘bite’ of country’s minimum wages relative to the median hourly pay among
33 These calculations are based on the OBR’s March 2023 forecast for CPI and Average Weekly Earnings, and outturn data for those
from ONS.
1980 to 1998: Pre-
minimum wage
1998 to 2015:
Minimum wage era
2015 to 2022: National
Living Wage era
-1%
0%
1%
2%
3%
4%
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Lower <- Percentile of hourly pay -> higher
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
39
full-time workers rather than all workers. On this basis, in 2022 the bite of the UK
minimum wage was 59 per cent, which (comparing to the OECD’s 2021 data) puts the
UK in 10th place among OECD countries, though if we limited the comparison to the
richer countries, the UK’s minimum wage would be in 5th place (behind New Zealand,
Portugal, Korea and France). By 2024, if the target of reaching two-thirds of the median
is met, the UK minimum wage bite relative to full-time workers is likely to rise to 62 per
cent. This would put the UK’s minimum wage above France and Koreas, if those countries
don’t make similarly large increases. The 2022 (red bar) and estimated 2024 (yellow bar)
minimum wage bites are shown in Figure 14 below, alongside the bites in 2021 across
OECD countries.
FIGURE 14: The UK is on course to have one of the highest minimum wages in
the world
Minimum wage relative to median pay among full-time employees: OECD countries
(2021) and UK (2022, and in 2024 if meet current target)
NOTES: Estimate for 2024 based on raising the minimum wage to two thirds of median hourly pay among
workers aged 21 and above. This is converted into a bite relative to full-time workers, in accordance with
how the OECD calculate its measure of the ‘bite’ of the minimum wage.
SOURCE: OECD, and Analysis of ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings.
29%
42%
43%
43%
45%
45%
45%
46%
46%
47%
48%
50%
50%
51%
52%
52%
52%
55%
55%
55%
57%
59%
60%
61%
61%
62%
66%
68%
71%
72%
82%
92%
0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
United States
Latvia
Estonia
Czech Republic
Belgium
Japan
Hungary
Ireland
Netherlands
Lithuania
Spain
Canada
Greece
Germany
Israel
Australia
Slovak Republic
Romania
Luxembourg
Poland
Mexico
UK: 2022
Slovenia
France
Korea
UK: 2024, if target met
Portugal
New Zealand
Türkiye
Chile
Costa Rica
Colombia
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
40
The minimum wage is therefore an example of a labour market regulation where the
UK has a high minimum compared to other countries, and where this level has been
raised in an ambitious way. This has significantly strengthened wage growth for bottom
earners, and has drastically curbed hourly wage inequality. And importantly, to date, a
rising minimum wage has not had a significant negative impact on employment, so the
minimum wage has been an unambiguously successful policy (Box 2 below provides a
summary of the literature on the effects of the minimum wage on different outcomes).
There remain the caveats that the minimum wage doesn’t benefit low-paid self-employed
workers (who comprise a third of all workers on low hourly pay).
34
, and the fact that it
has a smaller impact on rates of low weekly pay, which is arguably what matters most
from a living standards perspective. The more muted impact on low weekly pay is mainly
because only a minority of workers in low weekly pay are on low hourly pay – many are on
higher pay but work low hours.
35
Low weekly pay (defined, in keeping with low hourly pay,
as earning less than two-thirds of median weekly pay) has fallen since 2015, but only by 4
percentage points (from 29.4 per cent of employees in 2015 to 25.2 per cent in 2022).
36
The following section will show that the situation when it comes to other areas of labour
market regulation, including sick pay and protection against hours and pay insecurity, is
very different, with little or no progress made, and the level of minimum standards much
lower in the UK than in other countries.
34 N Cominetti et al., Low Pay Britain 2022: Low pay and insecurity in the UK labour market, Resolution Foundation, May 2022.
35 N Cominetti et al., Low Pay Britain 2022: Low pay and insecurity in the UK labour market, Resolution Foundation, May 2022.
36 Source: RF analysis of ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings.
37 A Manning, The elusive employment effect of the minimum wage, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Winter 2021.
BOX 2: What do we know about the impact of the minimum wage?
A vast literature on minimum wages
exists for people looking to understand
its effects. Much of this has focused
on whether minimum wages affect
the employment of those whose
pay is pushed up, but there are also
many studies looking at impacts on
prices, profits, productivity, and other
outcomes. In this Box we provide a brief
summary of this literature.
Negative effects on employment
from minimum wages have so far, in
the words of Alan Manning, proved
elusive, going against what textbook
economics would predict.
37
Arin Dubes
important 2019 review concluded that
estimates of the ‘own wage elasticity’
from the minimum wage to date (the
extent to which workers’ employment
falls compared to the extent to which
the minimum wage pushes up their
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
41
pay) are centred on zero.
38
This can
also be seen in the descriptive data,
with employment rates for the groups
of workers more likely to earn the
minimum wage (such as those with
low qualifications) are similar to their
historic levels.
39
The literature gives a number of
explanations. One is that employers
have more wage bargaining power than
workers, which means that absent
a minimum wage workers’ pay is low
relative to the value they produce –
the minimum wage is eating into this
downward pressure. Another is that
minimum wages ‘pay for themselves,
either by lowering other employment
costs (such as by reducing worker
turnover and hiring costs), or by raising
productivity (including by inducing
more effort from workers). At the level
of the whole economy, evidence from
Germany has also found that the
minimum wage can have a positive
effect on productivity by pushing the
reallocation of workers away from
smaller less productive firms, and
towards larger and more productive
firms and sectors.
40
It is also possible to avoid
disemployment effects if employers
adjust to higher wage costs through
other channels, and there is indeed
evidence of employers raising
prices and accepting lower profits in
38 A Dube, Impacts of minimum wages: review of the international evidence, November 2019.
39 Low Pay Commission, Low Pay Commission Report 2022, January 2023.
40 C Dustmann et al., Reallocation Effects of the Minimum Wage, 2020.
41 Cribb et al, The impact of the National Living Wage on wages, employment and household incomes, December 2021.
response to higher minimum wages.
The particular margin of adjustment
will depend on the market a company
operates in (firms in tradeable sectors
are less likely to be able to raise prices
in response to minimum wage hikes)
and how easy it is for the firm to change
its production processes (i.e. to use
more capital and less labour).
All of the above being said, most
economists would agree that at some
point minimum wages are likely to
have a negative effect on employment.
And this becomes more likely as the
minimum wage rises – empirical studies
can of course only tell us about the
impacts of past (lower) minimum wage
levels, and leave the impact of higher
minimum wage levels uncertain. And its
notable that the most recent significant
study of employment effects in the
UK – a 2021 study by the Institute of
Fiscal Studies, which looked at the
years following the introduction of the
National Living Wage – did identify
a negative employment effect, with
a central estimate of an own wage
elasticity of -0.17.
41
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
42
Section 4
Minimum standards beyond the minimum wage
Pay is clearly important for quality work. But other aspects of work like security,
autonomy and dignity clearly matter a lot as well. Half of private-sector employees say
they would be willing to turn down a pay rise for a range of improvements – some boil
down to working less for the same pay (including workers who wanted more holiday,
or to work fewer hours) but some are completely separate from pay, including workers
who wanted work to be more meaningful, or to be treated with more dignity at work.
In this context, we assess the level of the UK’s minimum standards when it comes
to some aspects of work beyond pay, and, in particular, areas where regulation can
set a minimum floor. The overall finding is that the UK’s minimum standards are in
many areas low compared to other countries, and that this contributes to inequality
because high earners tend to be offered occupational entitlements that far exceed
the legal minimum.
We show that the UK’s minimum sick pay rate is the lowest among all OECD countries
(aside from the United States and South Korea which offer no statutory sick pay, or
SSP). This low rate mainly affects the lowest income (private-sector) workers with
four-in-ten telling us in March 2023 they’d expect to receive SSP (rather than being
paid as normal), compared to only one-in-twenty of the highest income survey
respondents (those earning above £50,000). Beyond sick pay, the UK offers fewer days
holiday than other comparable rich countries, and maternity pay in the UK offers a
much lower replacement rate. Our survey evidence found that well over twice the
share of the lowest-paid women aged under 45 would expect to rely on statutory
maternity pay, or not be paid at all, compared to the highest-paid women.
In the previous section we showed just how much progress has been made on reducing
low pay, largely thanks to the success of a higher minimum wage. But as we have already
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
43
discussed in Section 2, there is much more to work than just pay. So in this section we
assess minimum standards when it comes to other areas of labour market regulation,
namely: sick pay, holiday pay, maternity pay and protection against hours and pay
insecurity.
Pay isn’t the only thing that matters to workers – conditions, hours,
and protections are all important too
Pay clearly matters, but when we asked private-sector workers in March 2023 which
features of work (aside from pay) would make the biggest positive difference at work, we
can see that other non-pay aspects are important too (see the left-hand panel of Figure
15). The two features of work that were selected by the most respondents are related to
pay, in that they involve working less without necessarily losing pay. These were more
paid holidays (selected by 16 per cent of respondents), and to work fewer hours (12
per cent). But there were several commonly-chosen improvements which were quite
different to pay. For 11 per cent, lower work intensity (chosen by 11 per cent) was the most
important improvement. Other notable choices were being treated by more dignity and
respect (chosen by 5 per cent) and more meaningful work (chosen by 3 per cent).
We also asked workers if they be willing to turn down a wage rise for the improvement
they selected (with pay rise options from 1 to 10 per cent). As shown in the right-hand
panel of Figure 15, more flexible work, better sick pay, as well as fewer hours or more pail
holiday are all dimensions for which at least half of workers would be willing to turn down
a pay rise (with some even willing to turn down a 10 per cent pay rise).
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
44
FIGURE 15: Workers would be willing to trade-off pay rises for better quality
work
Proportion of employees reporting which non-pay feature would make the biggest
positive difference at work (left-side) and for that selected feature what share would be
willing to turn down a wage rise for that improvement (right-side): UK, 10-14 March 2023
NOTES: Base is all private-sector employees (n=2,011). Only includes responses where sample size is at
least 50. More paid holiday (n=322), Fewer hours (n=241), Work to be less intense (n=222), More flexible
hours (n=149), More WFH (n=126), Advancement prospects (n=125), Better pension scheme (n=107), More
dignity/ respect (n=94), Better sick pay (n=89), More meaningful work (n=62) and Control over work (n=51).
SOURCE: Analysis of YouGov, March 2023 survey.
Splitting these results by income shows a similar picture but strikingly lower-paid workers
put much weight on higher sick pay. If we segment the left-hand panel of Figure 15 into
those with an individual income above and below £25,000T, the top four most popular
choices are identical (albeit in a slightly different order): more paid holiday, work to be
less intense, more flexible hours and fewer hours. There are, however, some differences:
for example, over twice the share of the lower -income group (7 per cent) chose better
sick pay as the non-pay feature of work that would make the biggest difference compared
to than the higher-income group (3 per cent). Starting with sick pay, then, we next assess
some of these non-pay areas of work which are clearly important for workers and where it
is possible to set higher minimum standards.
It is noteworthy that Splitting these results by income when we segment the left-
hand panel of Figure 15 into those with an individual income above and below £25,000,
the results remain remarkably similar. The top four most popular choices are identical
(albeit in a slightly different order): more paid holiday, work to be less intense, more
flexible hours and fewer hours. There are, however, some differences: for example, over
twice the share of the lower -income group (7 per cent) chose better sick pay as the
3%
3%
4%
5%
5%
6%
6%
7%
11%
12%
16%
0% 10% 20%
Control over work
More meaningful work
Better sick pay
More dignity/ respect
Better pension scheme
Advancement prospects
More WFH
More flexible hours
Work to be less intense
Fewer hours
More paid holiday
Biggest positive difference at work
47%
57%
42%
34%
56%
49%
56%
57%
55%
66%
57%
0% 25% 50% 75%
% willing to turn down wage rise for improvement
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
45
non-pay feature of work that would make the biggest difference compared to than the
higher -income group (3 per cent). Starting with sick pay, then, we next assess some of
these non-pay areas of work which are clearly important for workers and that policy is
amenable to.
42
UK Statutory Sick Pay offers very little insurance, predominantly
affecting low-paid workers
UK employees are legally entitled to Statutory Sick Pay (SSP), which is zero pay for the
first three days of sickness absence and a flat rate of £109.40 per week after the fourth
day.
43
Employers can, however, offer a more generous arrangement than this statutory
minimum if they want to (which is often referred to as occupational sick pay). To be
covered for SSP workers must be classed as an employee or agency worker and earn at
least the Lower Earnings Limit (LEL), which is £123 a week.
Figure 16 shows that the UK’s SSP arrangement is very low by international standards.
Sick pay only covers around 11 per cent of a full-time private-sector average employees
wages in the first four weeks of sickness – compared to the OECD median of a 64 per
cent replacement rate.
44
This replacement rate for sick workers is only higher than
South Korea or the United States (at a federal level) – the only OECD or G20 countries
which don’t currently offer statutory sick pay. Indeed, the UK is one of only a handful of
European countries that doesn’t have compulsory earnings-related payments; and the
only OECD country in which employers provide a fixed amount from the start of a spell
of sickness. Many other European countries either pay full wages (including the likes of
Iceland, Germany, Austria, Luxembourg) or a percentage of earnings between 50 and 90
per cent for an initial period.
45
Most other European and OECD countries also provide
sick pay from day one and do not impose a waiting period for eligible employees.
46
The
UK’s ‘waiting period’ of 3 days is, however, in line with the 3-day maximum recommended
by the ILO convention.
The UK’s SSP system is relatively unique in that the low flat rate of sick pay is funded
solely by employers for a period of up to 28 weeks. Most OECD countries only have
42 It is worth noting that we only scratch the surface when it comes to employment and overall income protection measures.
We will be exploring the adequacy of the overall welfare state and other forms of income protection in separate Economy 2030
papers. For a comprehensive discussion of UK employment insurance see: A Harrop, H Reed & E Sacares, In time of need: Building
employment insurance for all, Fabian Society, March 2023.
43 During the coronavirus crisis SSP was made available from the first day of sickness and for workers forced to self-isolate. On the 24
March 2022 these rules no longer applied. For a more detailed discussion of SSP during the crisis, see: M Brewer & M Gustafsson,
Time out: Reforming Statutory Sick Pay to support the Covid-19 recovery phase, Resolution Foundation, December 2020.
44 These OECD figures are from 2019. In 2019 SSP in the UK was £94.25 a week and the average weekly wage for a full-time private-
sector worker was £706. If a worker on this wage took four weeks of sickness absence they would receive £320.45 in SSP (£94.25 x
(17/5)) compared to their usual wage over four weeks of £2,824 (£706 x 4). So, SSP would only replace 11 per cent (£320.45 / £2,824)
of the average full-time private-sector workers’ wage. Source: Analysis of ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings.
45 Denmark and Australia offer fixed rate sickness benefits to employees when employer-provided sick (that fully replaces earnings)
has come to an end.
46 OECD (forthcoming), Disability, Work and Inclusion in Korea: Towards equitable and adequate social protection for sick workers,
OECD Publishing, Paris.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
46
statutory sick pay periods covered by the employers that last between 5 and 15 days
(after which point sickness benefits tend to come into play).
47
This helps explain why in
an initial two-week period of absence three-quarters of income replacement is paid for by
employers across all OECD countries. But over a longer period of 12 weeks, on average,
two-thirds comes from the state with the remaining one-third from employers.
48
FIGURE 16: Statutory Sick Pay in the UK offers a very low level of income
protection compared to the systems in other OECD countries
Replacement rate of statutory sick pay or equivalent system for the first four weeks of
sickness: OECD countries, 2019
NOTES: The results refer to an eligible full-time private-sector employee who is married, has no kids, is
aged 40, is earning an average wage and working with the same employer for one year who cannot work
from home.
SOURCE: Analysis of OECD.
In the UK, the requirement to earn above the LEL excludes close to 1.6 million low-
paid employees (1.3 million of which are in the private-sector) who are ineligible for this
47 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paid sick leave to protect income, health and jobs through the
COVID-19 crisis, OECD Policy Responses to Coronavirus (COVID-19), July 2020.
48 OECD (forthcoming), Disability, Work and Inclusion in Korea: Towards equitable and adequate social protection for sick workers,
OECD Publishing, Paris.
NA
NA
0% 25% 50% 75% 100%
United States
Korea
United Kingdom
Ireland
New Zealand
Canada
Italy
Portugal
Slovak Republic
Denmark
Mexico
Australia
Czech Republic
Spain
Costa Rica
Japan
Turkey
Lithuania
Estonia
Greece
Hungary
Sweden
Colombia
Finland
Netherlands
France
Israel
Latvia
Slovenia
Poland
Belgium
Switzerland
Norway
Austria
Germany
Luxembourg
Chile
Iceland
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
47
income replacement.
49
When we asked private-sector employees what their expected
pay would be if they took a week off through sickness, one-in-ten (12 per cent) of low-
income workers (earning below £20,000) expected no sick pay compared to one-in-
twenty of high-income workers (in this case defined as earnings above £60,000).
We also find that the lowest-paid workers are most reliant on the UK’s internationally
low rate of sick pay. As Figure 17 highlights, four-in-ten private-sector employees earning
below £20,000 only expect to receive SSP if they have to take a week off work through
illness, compared to fewer than a tenth of those earning above £50,000.
On the flipside, rich workers can expect a more generous deal from their employers
when it comes to sick pay.
50
As Figure 17 shows almost quadruple the share of the
highest-income workers (79 per cent) expect to get their normal rate of pay when sick
in comparison to the lowest-income workers (22 per cent). Even though gross income
(which for most workers is wages and salaries) is not the be all and end all, higher
incomes appear to be associated with other non-pay work benefits like more generous
sick pay.
Overall, SSP in the UK offers very little insurance against sickness, particularly when
compared to other rich countries, and as we have shown this mainly affects low-paid
workers. These views are recognised by employers, too, with almost two-thirds (62 per
cent) of employers surveyed by the Chartered Institute of Personnel and Development in
2021 agreeing that the SSP rate is too low and should be increased.
51
49 Source: Analysis of ONS, Labour Force Survey.
50 These results are similar to other UK-based surveys. See: Trades Union Congress, Sick pay that works: TUC report on the urgent
need for reform, February 2021.
51 Chartered Institute of Personnel and Development, What should an effective sick pay system look like? Recommendations for
ensuring a financial safety net for workers during illness, December 2021.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
48
FIGURE 17: Low-income workers receive a poor version of sick pay compared to
high-income workers
Expected pay if employee took a week off work through sickness, by gross individual
income band: UK, 10-14 March 2023
NOTES: Base is all private-sector employees (n=2,011). All also includes those who didn’t give an income
figure. Under £20,000 (n=330), £20,000-£29,999 (n=477), £30,000-£39,999 (n=340), £40,000-£49,000 (n=238),
£50,000-£59,000 (n=144) and £60,000 plus (n=223). The figures here combine answers to multiple survey
questions and have been independently analysed by the Resolution Foundation.
SOURCE: Analysis of YouGov, March 2023 survey.
UK minimum paid holiday also lags behind our peers but many UK
workers - especially those in high-paid jobs – get more
UK workers are legally entitled to at least 28 days paid annual leave a year (including bank
holidays, which, if taken, leaves 20 remaining days per year). As we have already shown,
there is unsurprisingly, a desire among workers for more paid holidays, with 57 per cent
willing to turn down a pay rise to gain more holiday. And comparisons with other rich
nations suggest that British workers have reason to expect more. The statutory minimum
number of holiday days in the UK is three days below the OECD median (31); and the UK
ranks 27th out of 36 OECD countries when it comes to the generosity of statutory annual
leave. Countries like Austria (38 days), France (36 days), Spain (36 days), Luxembourg
(35 days) and Sweden (35 days) have far more generous holiday entitlements (including
public holidays) than the UK.
52
Analysis of the UK Labour Force Survey (LFS) does, however, show that most workers (82
per cent) get more than the UK’s minimum holiday entitlement (as shown in Figure 18).
But a much higher share of the highest-paid quintile of employees (93 per cent) receive
a more generous version of annual leave when compared to the lowest-paid quintile of
52 Source: Table g5-4 in: OECD Employment Outlook 2021, July 2021.
12%
6%
6%
31%
21%
15%
9%
8%
4%
17%
12%
10%
11%
9%
6%
5%
10%
22%
44%
55%
67%
71%
79%
50%
0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
Under £20,000
£20,000-£29,999
£30,000-£39,999
£40,000-£49,999
£50,000-£59,999
£60,000 plus
All
Not paid
SSP (£99/week)
Above SSP
(< normal)
Normal pay
Other/ don't
know
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
49
employees (66 per cent). Not only that, the lowest-paid employees are much more likely
to report either no annual leave or something below the statutory minimum (both of
which are labour-market violations) when compared to the highest-paid employees (12
per cent versus 2 per cent of employees, respectively). In short, the majority of workers in
all pay categories are above the ‘floor’ when it comes to annual-leave days, but some low-
paid workers experience a rough deal – particularly those being denied their statutory
rights.
53
FIGURE 18: Most workers get above the statutory minimum holiday entitlement
Number of days’ annual leave among full-time employees, by hourly pay quintile: UK,
2005-2021
NOTES: Considers the larger number of bank holidays in Scotland (10) and Northern Ireland (9) compared
to rest of UK (8).
SOURCE: Analysis of ONS, Labour Force Survey.
Like sick pay, Statutory Maternity Pay is low in the UK, mainly
affecting low-paid workers
In the UK, female employees are entitled to 39 weeks of Statutory Maternity Pay (SMP),
which is 90 per cent of their normal pay for the first 6 weeks dropping to a flat rate of
£172.48 per week for the next 33 weeks. Most other European and OECD countries
offer more generous maternity pay which generally involve earnings-related payments
for most of the statutory leave duration. According to the OECD, for a woman earning
average pay in the private-sector, SMP would replace 27 per cent of earnings over a
one-year maternity pay leave, compared to the median replacement rate of 40 per cent
53 We discuss this labour market violation i.e. receiving less than the statutory minimum holiday entitlement in more detail here: N
Cominetti, C McCurdy & H Slaughter, Low Pay Britain 2021, Resolution Foundation, June 2021.
13%
5%
9%
14%
20%
22%
34%
32%
34%
37%
36%
29%
28%
34%
31%
27%
23%
19%
21%
27%
23%
18%
16%
18%
0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
All
5 - highest paid
4
3
2
1 - lowest paid
Zero Nonzero, below statutory Statutory 1-5 additional 6-10 additional 11+ additional
Hourly
pay
quintile
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
50
across OECD countries (as shown in Figure 19). This is in stark contrast to some Eastern
European and Scandinavian countries like Estonia (100 per cent). Lithuania (100 per cent),
Poland (80 per cent), Sweden (72 per cent) and Norway (69 per cent) that replace well
over of half of female employees’ pay in the year after birth. In fact, there are 14 OECD
countries where the replacement rate is above 50 per cent.
FIGURE 19: The UK’s Statutory Maternity Pay is relatively ungenerous
compared to other rich countries
Average wage replacement (if on statutory maternity leave for one year) and duration of
statutory maternity payments in OECD countries, 2022
SOURCE: Analysis of Table PF2.1 in OECD, Family Database.
So, the UK’s SMP is relatively ungenerous when compared to other rich countries, but
how does the experience of SMP differ across the income distribution? As with sick pay
and holiday days, it is the lowest-paid workers that receive this entitlement. In our survey
we asked female employees if they had a child now, and wanted to take nine months off,
what would be their expected pay. As Figure 20 shows, two-thirds (65 per cent) of female
workers under the age of 45 earning below £20,000 expect to either receive SMP, or not
be paid at all, compared to 28 per cent of female workers with an income over £40,000.
NA
0% 50% 100%
United States
New Zealand
France
Australia
Ireland
Switzerland
Netherlands
Cyprus
United Kingdom
Greece
Czech Republic
Belgium
Spain
Malta
Austria
Slovakia
Portugal
Italy
Denmark
Luxembourg
Germany
Canada
Finland
Japan
Latvia
Hungary
Romania
Norway
Sweden
Poland
Slovenia
Bulgaria
Estonia
Lithuania
Replacement rate (one year)
NA
0 13 26 39 52
United States
France
Netherlands
Switzerland
New Zealand
Spain
Cyprus
Australia
Malta
Czech Republic
Ireland
Slovakia
Portugal
Belgium
Luxembourg
Greece
Norway
Finland
United Kingdom
Italy
Denmark
Slovenia
Canada
Bulgaria
Japan
Hungary
Romania
Austria
Estonia
Germany
Lithuania
Latvia
Poland
Sweden
Duration of payments (weeks)
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
51
FIGURE 20: Low income female employees are reliant on Statutory Maternity
Pay
Expected pay if a female employee had a child now and wanted to take 9 months off, by
gross individual income band: UK, 10-14 March 2023
NOTES: Base is all private-sector female employees under 45 (n=327) All also includes those who didn’t
give an income figure. Don’t knows are excluded. Under £20,000 (n=53), £20,000-£29,999 (n=75), £30,000-
£39,999 (n=69), £40,000 plus (n=98). The figures here combine answers to multiple survey questions and
have been independently analysed by the Resolution Foundation.
SOURCE: Analysis of YouGov, March 2023 survey.
This income gradient is also clear when we look at the response from male employees
in our survey who were asked what their expected pay would be if they took two weeks
off after having a child.
54
Some 13 per cent of male employees with gross incomes below
£20,000 expect not to receive their statutory right to paternity pay, with a further 14 per
cent of men on incomes between £20,000 and £29,999 also expressing the same concern
(compared to 8 per cent for all private-sector male employees). Around half of all men in
the two lowest income groups expect to receive Statutory Paternity Pay, which is over
three times the share of men in the highest income group.
54 After childbirth, male employees are legally entitled to 2 weeks’ Statutory Paternity Pay, which is £172.48 a week or 90 per cent of
their normal pay, whichever is lower.
8% 57%
49%
26%
25%
38%
28%
47%
69%
62%
53%
0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
Under £20,000
£20,000-£29,999
£30,000-£39,999
£40,000 plus
All
Not paid
SMP
Above SMP or
normal pay
Paid (but not
other options)
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
52
FIGURE 21: There is a clear income gradient when it comes to Statutory
Paternity Pay
Expected pay if a male employee had a child now and wanted to take two weeks off, by
gross individual income band: UK, 10-14 March 2023
NOTES: Base is all private-sector male employees (n=1,056). All also includes those who didn’t give an
income figure. Under £20,000 (n=102), £20,000-£29,999 (n=238), £30,000-£39,999 (n=196), £40,000-£49,999
(n=155), £50,000-£59,999 (n=89) and £60,000 plus (n=154).
SOURCE: Analysis of YouGov, March 2023 survey.
Overall, there is a clear case for trying to match impetus behind raising the minimum
wage floor to other areas of labour market regulation. The most obvious example in this
context is sick pay, which is low by international standards, adversely affecting low-paid
workers. We’ve also had little progress on protection against hours and pay insecurity –
both of which are most concentrated in the lowest paid jobs.
55
And as we have shown
in Section 2, these types of insecurity, for example when it comes to hours worked, can
have particularly pernicious effects on wellbeing and happiness. In the next section we
set out a policy agenda for improving low-paid work through higher minimum standards
which would give workers in that group the respect and dignity they deserve.
55 N Cominetti et al., Low Pay Britain 2022: Low pay and insecurity in the UK labour market, Resolution Foundation, May 2022.
13%
14%
6%
4%
4%
6%
0%
8%
53%
47%
33%
33%
30%
15%
36%
22%
24%
27%
29%
21%
29%
26%
9%
14%
31%
33%
43%
48%
27%
0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
Under £20,000
£20,000-£29,999
£30,000-£39,999
£40,000-£49,999
£50,000-£59,999
£60,000 plus
All
Paid nothing
Receive/
expect SPP
Expect better
than SPP
Normal
weekly pay
Paid (not
other options)
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
53
Section 5
Improving low-paid work through higher
minimum standards
The UK needs a new policy agenda for improving low-paid work. This should of course
include more progress on the minimum wage. But other priority areas for urgent
action include a better sick pay system, stronger protections against insecurity, and
also areas such as annual leave entitlements and parental pay, where the UK lags
other countries.
On the minimum wage, the Government must decide what remit to set the Low
Pay Commission after 2024, when the current target of two-thirds of median hourly
pay is expected to be reached. The Government should set a new target path which
continues the recent pace of uprating, potentially reaching a ‘bite’ of 73 per cent of
median hourly pay by 2029. But policy makers need to think harder about a framework
for deciding when to stop uprating, which requires a difficult judgement about the
relative weight to place on wages and employment. Specifically, a new minimum wage
target should be more explicit about whether to accept somewhat lower employment
as a price, and if so how much. This will make the Low Pay Commissions job much
easier when it comes to weighing up the evidence it gathers.
Beyond the minimum wage, priority areas for reform include making the UK’s
Statutory Sick Pay system much more generous (we suggest moving to a system
based on 65 per cent earnings replacement), and offering workers on unpredictable
hours more control. There may also be a case for improving the UK’s floor when it
comes to parental pay, and the minimum level of holiday entitlement. All of these
measures would add to labour costs, and so raising standards on multiple fronts
should be overseen by the Low Pay Commission, who can monitor impact and advise
Government.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
54
At the start of this report we argued that a new economic strategy for the UK should
have better work at its centre, and that direct intervention through higher minimum
standards on pay and conditions is an important way of achieving that, especially
outside the big cities where the growth of new jobs in tradeable or high-value services is
unlikely. The UK already has one very important part of this strategy right – an ambitious
minimum wage policy which has had a transformative impact on the wages of the lowest
paid workers. However, as we argued in Sections 2 and 4, there is more to good work than
pay, and there are important areas where standards in the UK are low compared to other
countries and where there has been little progress, with the result that too many low-
paid workers lack security and dignity at work. In this section we set out what should be
the priority areas for reform.
Progress on the minimum wage should continue, with a new target
after 2024 based on a similar pace of uprating
Section 3 showed the significant impact that the minimum wage has had on the wages
of low earners, one that has strengthened in the National Living Wage era. To date, most
of the empirical evidence suggests this hasn’t come at the cost of substantial job losses
(although a recent study by the Institute for Fiscal Studies did find a small negative
employment effect).
56
The current minimum wage target – to reach two-thirds of median
hourly pay – is due to be met in 2024. This means the Government will have to decide this
year what policy to set after this point.
The Government should continue to set minimum wage policy in the same vein, namely
it should set an ambitious target relative to median hourly pay, and task the Low Pay
Commission with reaching this target while monitoring the effects of rate rises closely.
To some degree the target level is arbitrary. What really matters is the pace at which the
minimum wage is raised (relative to typical pay), and a framework for deciding when to
stop uprating. We discuss each of these in turn.
There is no empirical evidence to say what the ‘right’ pace of uprating is, but there are
two reasons why overly fast uprating might be risky. First, it could make it harder for
employers to adjust in a positive way, for example by investing in training or equipment
to boost productivity and make up for higher costs, which could in turn make a negative
employment effect more likely. Second, faster uprating increases the size of any
overshoot’ and the length of time required to get back to the ‘right’ level. We can only
gather evidence on the effect of a minimum wage uprating after the fact. And assuming
policy makers plan to uprate until sufficient negative effects are observed, this will mean
that the minimum wage will already be ‘too high’ when these effects are observed. In
56 J Cribb et al., The impact of the National Living Wage on wages, employment and household incomes, The Institute for Fiscal
Studies, December 2021.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
55
practice, policy makers are unlikely to lower the minimum wage in cash terms – and may
also be reluctant to lower it in real terms – which means rowing backwards on uprating
would come from holding the nominal or real value of the minimum wage constant and
waiting for wage growth to erode its relative value. We explored this issue in more detail
in our 2019 Low Pay Britain report.
57
Uprating at the National Living Wage era (2015-2022)
average pace – that is, raising the bite by 1.2 percentage points per year – would mean
it would normally be possible to ‘undo’ a one-year overshoot in a single year by freezing
in nominal terms (given average nominal wage growth from 2008-2022 of 2.4 per cent). It
would of course take substantially longer to undo any minimum wage rises if freezing in
real terms, as real wage growth has been roughly zero since 2008.
For both these reasons, it seems sensible to not go faster than the recent 1.2 percentage
points of median pay per year. Sticking to this pace, policy makers could set a target of
73 per cent in 2029 (i.e. by the likely the end of the next parliament). This target path is
illustrated in Figure 22. On current wage growth forecasts that would mean reaching a
value of £13.12 in 2029, worth £25,660 per year to someone working full-time.
58
FIGURE 22: Continuing to increase the minimum wage at its recent pace
implies a ‘bite’ target of 73 per cent by 2029 (the end of the next Parliament)
‘Bite’ of minimum wage (value relative to median hourly pay), outturn, current target
path, and future target path if minimum wage uprating continues at recent pace: UK
NOTES: Potential target path based on continuation of pace of increase in ‘bite’ (value of minimum wage
relative to median hourly pay of target group) from 2016 to 2022 of 1.2 percentage points per year.
SOURCE: Analysis of Low Pay Commission, 2022 report.
57 N Cominetti, K Henehan & S Clarke, Low Pay Britain 2019, Resolution Foundation, May 2019.
58 Based on comparing 72.6 per cent bite against current median pay (derived from OBR project of NLW in 2024 and published target
bite of two-thirds of the median), uprated in line with OBR forecast of average hourly pay growth (forecast post 2027 based on
extending OBR’s forecast of growth in 2027). Source: OBR, Economic and Fiscal Outlook, March 2023.
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018 2022 2026 2030
60% bite target 2/3 bite target 73% bite target?
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
56
It’s important to stress, however, that these target levels are only functions of the
uprating pace – there is no guarantee ahead of the fact that these levels would be
reached. What matters for that is a framework for deciding ‘how high is too high.
Policy makers need a clear framework for knowing when to stop
uprating – this may involve explicitly accepting a reduction in
employment
As the UK’s minimum wage rises, and reaches or passes the international frontier, the
chance of minimum wage upratings causing disemployment effects becomes higher,
and it becomes more important to have a clear framework for thinking about what the
right level of the minimum wage is, and when to stop uprating. At the moment, the
Governments framework for deciding when to stop uprating is vague.
The Governments current remit to the Low Pay Commission asks it to raise the minimum
wage in line with the target, but to stop ‘if the economic evidence warrants it’, and to
apply an ‘emergency brake’ on uprating if doing so would pose ‘significant risks to [lowest-
paid workers’] employment prospects. Similarly, the youth rates are to be raised ‘as high
as possible without damaging the employment prospects of each group.
59
The problem is the remit doesn’t say what ‘significant’ means, which makes it hard to use
to set policy. This isn’t a problem while estimates of disemployment effects are centred
around zero (as Arin Dube concluded in his 2019 review
60
), and there is no decision to
be made. But at some point, if the minimum wage keeps rising, the policy will eventually
start to create larger disemployment effects, at which point the Low Pay Commission will
need to know whether these justify pulling the ‘emergency brake’ and stopping uprating.
That’s not to say this is an easy question to answer. It requires a judgement about the
relative importance of employment and wages. Here we offer some initial thoughts to
help ground this debate.
We can start by ruling out the two most extreme positions. One (and a possible
interpretation of the Government’s language of ‘no significant risk to employment
prospects
61
) is that there is no acceptable negative employment effect, or that any
amount of disemployment effect is ‘too much. That we should reject this position is
clear from this example: if employment fell by 1 person in response to a minimum wage
59 Department for Business and Trade, National Minimum Wage and National Living Wage: Low Pay Commission remit 2022, March
2022.
60 A Dube, Impacts of minimum wages: review of the international evidence, November 2019.
61 Discussions with the Low Pay Commission and Government officials suggest that we might infer from the Government’s decision
making that this is not its position. The Office for Budget Responsibility publish forecasts which explicitly include a negative
impact on employment from minimum wage rises. Because the Government is aware of these forecasts and goes ahead with its
uprating, it might be thought to implicitly accept employment effects in line with the OBR’s forecasts. The OBR initially assumed
a disemployment parameter of -0.4, which it then lowered to -0.3 in 2018, which amounts to expecting employment to be 50,000
lower (with an equivalently sized effect on hours worked). On this line of thinking, the Government is happy to accept employment
effects at least as large as that. However, if this is the Government’s view, it would be better to set this out explicitly.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
57
uprating which benefited 1.7 million people (the number of people paid the minimum
wage in 2022), surely no one would deny this was worth doing. In the language of ‘own
wage elasticities’ (OWE), rejecting this position means saying that OWEs less than zero
may be acceptable.
62
In the same vein, we can also rule out OWEs approaching -1, where negative effects on
employment wholly wipe out the wage gains enjoyed by the affected group. This would
be the case if, for example, the minimum wage rose 10 per cent and employment among
workers on the minimum wage fell by 10 per cent (note that spillover effects would
mean there would also be effects on the wages and employment of workers earning
above the minimum wage). In this outcome, minimum wage workers as a whole don’t
benefit, in the sense that the wages paid going to minimum workers in aggregate are
unchanged. Moreover, the distributional consequences would be undesirable in that
some workers would lose all their labour income, and because unemployment has
negative consequences independent of its effect on income. It has a negative effect on
wellbeing (even after controlling for income)
63
, and, if lasting, is likely to have a negative
scarring’ effect on future earnings and employment.
64
Therefore a result where total
wages for a group are unchanged (because wages and employment fully offset) but
where employment has fallen is unambiguously a negative one.
Between these two polar cases it’s hard to be definitive about what an acceptable level
of employment effect is, not least because doing so requires a judgement about the
relative importance of wage increases and employment. There is a literature on ‘optimum
minimum wages (summarised in Annex 3), but constructing these estimates requires
a large modelling exercise which is beyond this paper. But we can offer some relevant
considerations about the appropriate balance of wages and employment in minimum
wage policy.
65
First, as alluded to above, data on subjective wellbeing can be used to get a rough
sense of the negative impact on wellbeing that results from being out of work. For
the purpose of illustration, the relationships we estimated in a 2019 paper would
suggest that a one unit increase in log income increases ‘happiness’ by 0.157 units,
while unemployment reduces it by 0.31 units. This alone could suggest placing a
62 The employment effect of the minimum wage is usually measured in terms of an estimated ‘own wage elasticity’ (OWE), which
is the percentage change in employment among a group following from a one percent rise in that groups wage induced by the
minimum wage. An OWE of zero would mean there was no impact on employment at all, while minus 1 would mean job losses fully
cancel out wage gains.
63 We published a report on wellbeing in 2019, which showed that unemployment has a significant negative effect on wellbeing even
controlling for income. Being unemployed, compared to being in a full-time employee job was associated with -0.7 lower ‘points’ on
life satisfaction, -0.3 for happiness, -0.5 for a sense that life is worthwhile, and -0.3 for freedom for anxiety (all measured on a scale
from 1 to 7). See, G Bangham, Happy Now? Lessons for economic policy makers from a focus on subjective well-being, February
2019.
64 For one of many papers estimating unemployment scarring effects, see: P Gregg & E Tominey, The Wage Scar from Youth
Unemployment, February 2004.
65 We are grateful to Anna Stansbury for providing insights here.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
58
ceiling on an acceptable OWE of around (minus) one-third.
66
Second, we know that unemployment doesn’t just have an effect on current
earnings and wellbeing, but can also lead to ‘scarring’ effects on a persons future
earnings and employment. Scarring effects are greater when the duration of
employment is longer. This is another reason to add weight to employment when
weighing these up against wage gains. A rough calculation suggests the present
value of the future scarring effects of higher unemployment could be worth 1 per
cent of wages for an OWE of one-third and a 10 per cent increase in the minimum
wage. This would reduce the net gain in wages by about one-eighth.
67
The distribution across workers of any increase in unemployment will affect any
welfare analysis. On one hand, the scarring effects of unemployment on the wages
of the employed may be small if all the extra unemployment incides upon a few
workers who remain unemployed forever. But on the other hand, such an outcome
would be unequal, with some workers getting higher wages forever, and other
workers losing all their wages.
The economic context also matters – during downturns long-term unemployment
rises, and the proportion of unemployment that is long-term rises – for example
in 2012 35 per cent of the unemployed had been out of work for a year or more,
compared to 20 per cent in 2005.
68
This means a given increase in unemployment
during a downturn is more likely to lead to longer spells out of work, and in those
periods policy makers should be more cautious and place greater weight on
employment.
Place also matters. If minimum wage rises cause distress to particular local labour
markets (i.e. if significant disemployment occurs within a concentrated area), this
might be more likely to lead to longer-term effects on the people working in those
areas. It’s already the case that there are some areas (including Hull, Blackpool,
Middlesborough, Wolverhampton, and Birmingham) where unemployment is
relatively high and where the minimum wage is high relative to local wages (see
Figure 23). The Low Pay Commission monitor developments in local labour
markets, and should continue doing so. But all else equal, an employment effect
concentrated on a subset of areas would be less desirable than one which was
66 The elasticity of utility U with respect to the minimum wage x can be written as dU/dx = (1+)+ p where  is the OWE,  is the
elasticity of utility with respect to income and p is the elasticity of utility with respect to the employment probability. The threshold
value of  at which the change in utility is zero is given by /(+p)
67 We take the baseline unemployment rate for the treated group to be 10 per cent and consider an increase of the minimum wage of
10 per cent. We simulate the increase in lifetime unemployment risk and assume that an additional year of unemployment reduces
wages when re-employed by 5 per cent, capped at two years. We assume that unemployment risk is uncorrelated across time
and discount lifetime earnings by 3 per cent per year. On these assumptions, the average loss in lifetime wages when employed
is 1 per cent when the minimum wage is increased. This is enough to wipe out approximately one-eighth of the net increase in
employment income.
68 Source: ONS, Labour Force Survey, via ONS, Labour Market Statistics.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
59
broader based (as it would be more likely to lead to longer-lasting effects), and
would therefore again warrant placing a higher weight on employment.
FIGURE 23: Some local areas would come under pressure from a higher
minimum wage
Unemployment rate (excluding full-time students) in 2021 and the minimum wage as a
proportion of local median hourly pay of residents in 2022 by local authority: GB
SOURCE: Analysis of ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings, 2022 and ONS, Census 2021.
Based on the above, what is the reasonable middle ground between accepting some
disemployment but wanting to steer well clear of minimum wage levels that are so
high that all gains are lost? In Arin Dubes 2019 review, he described OWEs of up to -0.4
as ‘small’, but our analysis of the wellbeing data above (i.e. accounting for the negative
impact on wellbeing of unemployment) suggests that a slightly more conservative value
of -0.3 might be a good place to start.
69
This is more specific and more ambitious than the
current remit.
What might this mean in practice? To give an indicative illustration, lets assume that the
target path shown in Figure 22 was followed, leading to a minimum wage with a 73 per
cent bite in 2029, and that an OWE of -0.3 was identified in that same year. Compared
to a world in which the minimum wage was held at its 2022 bite (i.e. it was uprated
with wage growth only), the minimum wage would be 18 per cent higher. Assuming the
OWE rose linearly to reach -0.3 (from -0.17 today, an assumption based on the IFS’s 2021
report
70
), employment would be 168,000 lower in 2029, of which 65,000 comes from lower
employment among employees paid at the minimum wage (-3.8 per cent), and 103,000
69 A Dube, Impacts of minimum wages: review of the international evidence, November 2019.
70 Cribb et al, The impact of the National Living Wage on wages, employment and household incomes, December 2021.
Middlesbrough
Redcar
Sunderland
Blackpool
Manchester
Hull
Bradford
Leicester
Nottingham
Birmingham
Sandwell
Wolverhampton
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90%
Places where minimum
wage is high relative to
local pay and with high
unemployment
Unemployment
rate (ex. full-time
students)
Bite of minimum wage
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
60
from lower employment among employees paid above the minimum wage but affected
by ‘spillover effects’ (-1.9 per cent), which are assumed to extend through the bottom
quarter of the wage distribution.
Overall, employment across the economy would be 0.5 per cent lower. This is not an
insignificant number – its the same as the lingering hit to employment post-pandemic
(employment in the three months to January 2023 was 0.5 per cent below the level
in the three months to March 2020). But of course, this needs to be set against the
improvement in wages experienced by (in this scenario) the UK’s 7 million lowest earners.
These numbers are only intended to give a sense of the scale of the effects we are
discussing, and they are specific to an employment elasticity of -0.3 being reached at
that level of minimum wage. They are sensitive to how quickly the employment elasticity
rose to that level. And they assume the entire effect happens through employment
rather than hours – the OBR typically assume that half the employment effect occurs
through lower hours worked (if we followed this approach, the above estimates of the
size of the employment effect would, naturally, be halved). In practice, of course, there is
no way of knowing at what level of minimum wage employment effects of that size would
be triggered. In the evidence to date, employment effects have, famously, proved ‘elusive,
so it may be possible to reach a much higher minimum wage before effects of this size
were found.
71
Ultimately, the difficulty of coming up with a precise response to the question of how to
weight employment and wages, and when to stop raising the ‘bite’ of the minimum wage,
should tell us that this is something the Government should be giving deliberate thought
to now. There has been little if any discussion of these questions in policy circles so far.
Having consistently made significant increases to the minimum wage, stopping uprating
(relative to median wages) will be a difficult and contentious decision when the time
comes, but easier if some of the intellectual groundwork has been laid in advance.
Policy makers must look beyond the minimum wage to improve
work – reforming statutory sick pay should be a priority
The minimum wage has clearly been a very important success, and should continue to
form the centre of any strategy to improve low-paid work. But pay is far from the only
thing which matters to workers. This is probably something that goes without saying, but
we also demonstrate this in our survey evidence in Section 4, where over half of workers
(53 per cent) said they would be willing to turn down a pay rise (sometimes a pay rise
of as much as 10 per cent) across all workers who chose a non-pay aspect of work they
would like to see improved.
71 A Manning, The elusive employment effect of the minimum wage, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Winter 2021.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
61
One of the areas most in need of reform is statutory sick pay (SSP). As the Coronavirus
crisis made clear, the current system is inadequate and means many people struggle to
make do while off work through sickness.
72
The fundamental problem is that SSP is set
at too low a level. This, combined with the three-day waiting period, means workers who
face time off through sickness and are reliant on SSP experience a significant income
hit. For someone working full-time on the minimum wage, a week’s absence through
sickness would currently mean receiving just £43.76 in SSP, just 11 per cent of their
normal earnings (£390.75). This matters because 40 per cent of the lowest paid workers
rely on SSP as their employer does not offer them an occupational sick pay scheme.
Of course, there are trade-offs to consider when it comes to designing a sick pay system.
Adequate income protection for workers needs to be set against the risk of shirking.
While for employers, there should be an incentive to help staff return to work (hence why
many countries expect employers to cover some or all of the cost of statutory sick pay),
73
a good system should also enable some amount of risk pooling (i.e. sharing the costs), so
that small employers are not overly exposed to losing staff to sickness.
The current system does not do a good job of balancing these trade-offs. Workers
have little incentive to shirk, but this comes at the expense of extremely low income
protection, while for employers there is no risk pooling (the UK is unusual in this
respect).
74
We suggest reforming SSP as follows:
SSP to replace 65 per cent of usual weekly earnings (this is close to the median
replacement rate across OECD countries of 64 per cent).
The waiting time before receiving SSP should be reduced from three days to one
day. This change could help reduce the early spread of illnesses and provide support
to the majority of workers who are only off sick for short durations.
SSP should be extended to workers with low weekly earnings i.e. those below the
Lower Earnings Limit (LEL) of £123 a week.
To limit costs, the earnings eligible for the 65% replacement could be capped at
£30,000 per year (£2,500/month), as was the case under the furlough scheme. This
would cap weekly SSP payments at £374.
These changes would make a big difference to the 4.1 million private-sector employees
who expect to get SSP if they fell ill under the current system, of which we estimate
72 Over Covid-19 the UK Government had to rapidly introduce reforms to improve the system (like reducing the waiting days to zero),
which have since been reversed. For a full discussion of SSP during Covid-19 see: M Brewer & M Gustafsson, Time out: Reforming
Statutory Sick Pay to support the Covid-19 recovery phase, Resolution Foundation, December 2020.
73 OECD, Disability, Work and Inclusion in Korea: Towards equitable and adequate social protection for sick workers, OECD
Publishing, (Forthcoming).
74 A Harrop, Statutory Sick Pay: Options for Reform, Fabian Society, June 2021.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
62
that around 1.4 million workers are actually in receipt of SSP in a given year. Extending
the eligibility criteria to include those below the LEL would mean 1.6 million (1.3 million
private-sector) additional workers would be eligible for statutory sick pay. As Annex 2
shows, the combination of sick pay starting from day two (rather than four) and earnings-
related sick pay of 65 per cent (rather than a flat rate) would see full and part-time
minimum wage workers remuneration for a week of sickness increase considerably
compared to the existing system (by £159.43 and £64.61, respectively in the illustrative
example).
Beyond better income protection, a more generous system would of course also
contribute to improved public health by reducing presenteeism and limiting the spread of
contagious diseases – we need only look at the improvements which had to be made to
SSP during Covid to see this.
75
Strikingly, during the pandemic, for example, care homes
that paid sick pay were significantly less likely to have seen Covid-19 cases rise.
76
A new scheme would have to consider the additional costs faced by employers. We
estimate that the additional annual SSP cost to employers of the changes described
above, if there were no changes in the number of sick days taken, would be £600 million
per year, a 140 per cent increase.
77
This increase would however represent just 0.1 per
cent of total annual spending on wages. And under this new scheme, we estimate SSP
costs would still only amount to 4 per cent of the amount spent on occupational sick pay
schemes.
There would be no change for the employers (and their workers) who already offer an
occupational sick pay scheme – which are commonplace among large employers (a 2019
government report found 77 per cent of employers with more than 250 staff offer an
occupational sick pay scheme) but rare among small employers (the same study found
just 26 per cent of employers with fewer than 50 staff do so).
78
This means most of the
additional SSP costs from moving to a more generous SSP system would be borne by
small businesses. And as mentioned above, it may be desirable to build into the scheme
a mechanism to lower small employers’ risk of facing very large SSP costs (i.e. from staff
with a long sickness absence). This used to be built into the UK’s system: even after full
SSP rebates ended in the 1990s, until 2014 the state reimbursed firms facing high SSP
75 S Chen et al., Tracking the Economic Impact of COVID-19 and Mitigation Policies in Europe and the United States, IMF Working
Paper 20 (125), July 2020. When Germany reduced sick pay generosity in 1996 it did indeed reduce shirking from work but it also
encouraged sick workers with contagious diseases to return to work, for example. N Ziebarth & S Pichler, The pros and cons of sick
pay schemes: Contagious presenteeism and noncontagious absenteeism behaviour, VoxEU, May 2018.
76 ONS, Impact of coronavirus in care homes in England: 26 May to 19 June 2020, July 2020.
77 This estimate is based on modelling in the Labour Force Survey. We construct a distribution of sickness absences in line with that
published in table A.6 in: DWP, Health and wellbeing at work: survey of employees, June 2015. We modify this by occupation group
(without changing the overall average sick days taken) based on ONS, Sickness absence in the labour market, 2018. Employees are
assumed to be in receipt of SSP based on their weekly pay and the data gathered in our YouGov survey (shown in Figure 17).
78 Department for Work and Pensions, Sickness absence and health in the workplace: understanding employer behaviour and
practice – an interim summary, June 2019.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
63
costs relative to their payroll.
79
Such reimbursements would involve additional public
spending, though if limited to support for costs resulting from longer sickness absences
these would be modest.
80
However, there would be additional downsides of such support
in the shape of deadweight costs (i.e. the state would be reimbursing some costs
which are currently borne through occupational sick pay schemes) and the fact that
the Government would effectively be providing a small subsidy to employment in small
businesses where productivity is on average lower.
Another important point is that we would expect improving the generosity of SSP to
lead to a behavioural change, and more sick days taken. Countries with more generous
sick pay systems tend to see more sick days taken on average. According to OECD
data, the average number of sick days taken per year is 4.5 in the UK, compared to 9.2 in
France and 11.7 in Germany, both of which have sick pay systems with replacement rates
comparable to the 65 per cent we have proposed (shown in Figure 24). If the number
of sick days taken by workers on SSP doubled, that would increase total additional SSP
costs by a further £900 million over and above the static impact set out above, bringing
the total additional SSP spending resulting from the policy change to £1.5 billion per
year.
81
This sounds like a large number, but this would still only represent 0.2 per cent
of total spending on wages and salaries per year, and just 8 per cent of the amount of
money employers currently spend on sick pay through occupational schemes.
79 A Harrop, Statutory Sick Pay: Options for Reform, Fabian Society, June 2021.
80 A recent Fabians report proposed a 50 per cent reimbursement for small employers (with fewer than 50 staff) for SSP costs
incurred for sickness absences lasting longer than six weeks. We estimate that the static cost to Government of such a scheme
(i.e. assuming no change in the number of sick days taken) would be £60m per year (based on 2022 wages and SSP system). For
Fabians proposal, see: A Harrop, H Reed & E Sacares, In time of need: Building Employment Insurance for All, Fabian Society, March
2023.
81 In addition to the notes in footnote 69, for our behavioural change results, we assume that sick days rise from 6 to 11 among the
lowest earners on SSP, from 5 to 9 among middle earners on SSP, and from 3 to 5 among high earners on SSP.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
64
FIGURE 24: Making SSP more generous would likely lead to workers taking
more sick days
Average number of days’ sick leave taken per year, and replacement rate of statutory
sick pay system (2020), by country
NOTES: Figure only displays countries where both the number of sick days and the replacement rate of
the sick pay system is available. Replacement rate is calculated based on average pay in private sector, and
based on four-week sickness absence.
SOURCE: Replacement date from: OECD, Supporting people and companies to deal with the COVID-19
virus: Options for an immediate employment, March 2020. Days sick day per year from OECD, Absence
from work due to illness.
Workers taking more sick days would also, of course, involve a loss of labour supply.
Taking the extreme case of a doubling of total sick days taken, that would reduce total
days worked per year by 1.7 per cent.
82
However, in reality we expect the effect would
be smaller since our proposal only affects those workers who don’t currently have an
occupational sick pay scheme: if only workers who don’t currently have an occupational
sick pay scheme doubled their sick days’ taken, this would instead involve a 0.7 per cent
reduction in days worked.
83
We should further bear in mind that many of the working
days being ‘lost’ here are days which are currently worked by sick people, who are likely to
be less productive than normal – so the impact on output would be smaller.
84
However,
these are still significant numbers. But they are an acceptable price to pay for a sick pay
system which treats workers with dignity.
82 This is a rough number, setting 4.5 days’ additional sick leave against 262 working days per year.
83 This is based on private sector workers without an occupational sick pay scheme doubling their days’ sick leave from 4.5 to 9, and
other workers remaining at 4.5 days.
84 S Ruhle et al., To work, or not to work, that is the question: Recent trends and avenues for research on presenteeism, European
Journal of Work and Organizational Psychology 29 (3), July 2019.
Austria
Germany
Finland
Switzerland
France
Slovenia
Belgium
Poland
Latvia
Australia
Israel
Estonia
Hungary
Spain
Greece
Lithuania
Turkey
Costa Rica
Czech Republic
Denmark
United States
Canada
Korea
United Kingdom
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
0% 25% 50% 75% 100%
Average sick days
taken per year
Replacement rate during 4-week sickness with statutory sickness protection
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
65
There is also more that can be done to protect workers against other
types of insecurity
Reforming sick pay would remove a real source of insecurity facing workers. No one
should have to face a significant income hit as a result of a few days’ illness. In the same
spirit of reducing problematic forms of insecurity, we can do more to protect to workers
who experience volatile hours and pay. This should include:
Giving workers a right to a contract with regular minimum hours where this reflects
their normal working pattern.
85
A right to at least two weeks’ advance notice of shifts, and compensation when
planned shifts are changed with less notice than that.
These recommendations were made five years ago in 2018 by the Low Pay Commissions
submission to Matthew Taylor’s Review into Modern Working Practices.
86
We have made
the case for these reforms in several reports ourselves – not least by showing the large
number of low-paid workers for whom unexpected changes to hours are a significant
source of anxiety.
87
Alongside these changes, we should also reduce the length of time workers’ have to
spend in a job before unfair dismissal law applies to 1 year – its level until it was raised
to 2 years in 2011. Currently, 2.4 million (42 per cent of) workers in the bottom hourly pay
quintile have been working for their employer for less than two years and therefore have
no protection against unfair dismissal (across all pay levels there are 8.5 million workers
with no unfair dismissal protection).
88
Other areas for reform could include boosting holiday entitlement
and making parental pay more generous
While we would certainly prioritise sick pay and new entitlements on regular hours,
we showed in Section 4 that there are other areas where the UK has a low regulatory
floor compared to other countries, and that these only really affect low-paid workers
(because high paid workers are likely to be offered a more generous arrangement by their
employer). Two areas where the UK could strengthen its offer are holiday entitlement and
parental pay.
85 To be clear this means we are not calling for the abolition of zero-hours contracts – for the reason that a significant number of
workers enjoy the benefits these offer. Instead, where workers would prefer a contract with stable guaranteed hours, and where
this is the reality of their work in practice (i.e. they have worked at least a minimum number of hours per week for a certain length
of time), they should be entitled to such a contract.
86 Low Pay Commission, Low Pay Commission Response to the Government on ‘one-sided flexibility’, December 2018.
87 N Cominetti et al, Low Pay Britain 2022: Low pay and insecurity in the UK labour market, May 2022
88 Source: Analysis of ONS, Labour Force Survey, 2022 datasets.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
66
On holiday entitlement, workers in the UK receive lower statutory holiday entitlement
than workers in many other rich countries. Including bank holidays, statutory holiday
entitlement in the UK is 28 days. This is three days lower than the median among OECD
countries of 31 days (which is what is offered in New Zealand, Estonia, Hungary, Finland
and Norway). Many countries offer much more – for example in France and Spain the
minimum is 36 days (25 days statutory annual leave plus 11 bank holidays in the case
of France), and in Austria a still higher 38 days (25 days statutory leave plus 13 bank
holidays). Our surveys of private-sector employees showed that more paid holiday was
the most commonly chosen item when presented with a list of things that would improve
work – chosen by 16 per cent of all respondents. There is therefore a strong case for
lifting the minimum holiday entitlement to at least the OECD median, which would mean
adding three days to the UK entitlement. As with sick pay, this would reduce the number
of days worked – here by roughly 0.2 per cent in total.
89
Importantly, and along with all the proposals in this section, this would particularly
benefit low-paid workers – for whom more paid holiday was also the number one choice
of factors that would improve work (selected by 14 per cent of respondents). That is
because low-paid workers are more likely to only receive the statutory minimum holiday:
among full-time workers, a third of those in the bottom hourly pay quintile receive either
the statutory minimum entitlement or say they don’t receive paid holiday at all (compared
to just 7 per cent of the highest paid quintile).
Similarly, there is a strong case for strengthening parental pay. Maternity pay in the UK
offers a much lower replacement rate (compared to a womans normal pay) than most
other rich countries. The OECD calculate that maternity pay would on average offer a
replacement rate of just 27 per cent, compared to the median OECD country of 40 per
cent (which is what is offered in Italy), and much higher rates of replacement in several
Eastern European and Scandinavian countries.
Again, this is something that affects low-paid workers much more than it does other
workers. Our survey evidence found that, among the lowest paid women aged under 45
(those earning below £20,000), and excluding those who said they didn’t know, two thirds
(65 per cent) would expect to rely on statutory maternity pay only while on maternity
leave or not be paid at all, compared to just 21 per cent of women earning above £50,000.
Parental pay wasn’t covered in depth in this report and therefore we don’t offer a detailed
policy proposal here. But the most compelling way of strengthening parental pay would
be to the extend the period during which the 90 per cent replacement rate is offered.
At present this lasts for just 6 weeks – which is hard to justify when the typical period of
89 This is based on analysis of the LFS which suggests 21.5 per cent of full-time employees receive less than or equal to the current
statutory minimum leave entitlement plus three days. Adding three days to those workers’ leave entitlement adds 0.6 days’ leave
per worker overall, which is 0.2 per cent of the 261 working days per year.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
67
maternity leave lasts for 9 months.
90
We should not expect low paid women to deal with
such a significant income hit when having a baby.
Higher minimum standards require stronger enforcement
Higher minimum standards raise the potential for non-compliance among employers. It
is therefore essential that they are accompanied by rigorous enforcement. Even with our
labour market standards where they are today, our enforcement system has significant
shortcomings. Around half a million employees are paid less than the (age-relevant)
minimum wage, partly because penalties for non-compliance are low.
91
And the main
system through which workers can seek redress – employment tribunals – does not do
a good job of helping low earners, who are most at risk of facing infringement of their
employment rights.
92
We have been conducting a research programme into labour market enforcement for the
past three years and will be publishing a final report with a full set of policy proposals at
the end of April 2023.
Raising minimum standards should be overseen by the Low Pay
Commission
We have discussed above the trade-offs involved in each of the specific policy areas.
However, because all of them are likely to increase employment costs to some degree, it
would be important for effects of these policies to be assessed in the round. Here there is
a clear role for the Low Pay Commission (LPC) – whose remit could be expanded to look
at low pay and conditions. The Government and LPC could treat the raising of minimum
standards beyond pay in the same way they do the minimum wage: the Government
should set the direction of travel, while the LPC should be tasked with evaluating impacts
and with advising Government on the timings and specifics of policy changes.
There is also the interesting question about whether there are trade-offs between the
minimum wage and non-pay minimum standards. It is possible that raising the minimum
wage will make employers look for cost savings elsewhere, which may include reducing
the non-pay amenities offered, especially to low paid workers. This might include
removing access to occupational sick pay schemes, reducing holiday entitlement, or
pushing for greater use of atypical employment (such as agency work and zero-hours
90 This was calculated using Understanding Society dataset for years 2009-2022, based on women who had returned to work after
childbirth, and who specified the date their child was born and the date they returned to work. Note that durations of maternity
leave don’t vary significantly by pay level. The median length was 8.9 months overall, and 9.0 months among women in the lowest
hourly pay quintile, and 8.2 months among women in the lowest hourly pay quintile. Pay is measured in womens job post-maternity
leave.
91 Source: RF analysis of ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings, 2022. For our report on minimum wage non-compliance, please
see: L Judge and A Stansbury, Under the wage floor: Exploring firms’ incentives to comply with the minimum wage, January 2020.
92 L Judge and N Cominetti, From rights to reality: Enforcing labour market laws in the UK, September 2019.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
68
contracts). The potential for these responses is a reason why it is important for these
other minimum standards to be raised alongside the minimum wage. We know that
workers place a value on many non-pay amenities (our survey evidence in Section 2
showed that more than half of private-sector employers would turn down a wage rise to
gain them) which means that a minimum wage rise which was paid for with the erosion of
non-pay amenities would be an undesirable outcome for many workers.
These proposals would not make the UK labour market less flexible
Many believe that the UK’s flexible labour market is an important part of its economic
model – promoting high employment (by reducing the risk attached to taking on new
workers) and encouraging the efficient allocation of labour, and thereby supporting (or
at least not hindering) productivity growth.
93
The strength of the relationship between
employment regulation and economic growth is not clear – not least because there are
examples of countries with higher productivity than the UK with both much lower (the
United States) and higher (France, Germany) levels of employment regulation.
94
But in
any case, it’s worth stressing that the higher minimum standards we propose here would
not be expected to have much impact on worker flows. Most would have an impact
on labour costs, but not through making hiring or firing more expensive. Our proposal
for reducing the unfair dismissal rule to one year is directly related to hiring and firing,
but when this rule was changed in 2011 there was no impact on the rate of involuntary
dismissals, so we would not expect any change from reversing this.
95
The above proposals wouldnt benefit the self-employed – where the
first priority should be to reduce ‘bogus’ self-employment, and to
remove the self-employment tax incentive
The above policy proposals would make a difference to millions of low earners. But they
all relate to employees rather than the self-employed, who are growing as a share of the
low-paid workforce (we estimated last year that a third of all low-paid workers are self-
employed).
96
There are of course ways in which some of the spirit of the proposals above
could be extended to the self-employed. A full discussion of options is beyond the scope
of this paper, but it would be possible to imagine the offering self-employed workers
earnings-linked sickness and parental leave insurance through the social security
system.
97
93 ‘Recent trends in employment protection legislation’ in: OECD Employment Outlook 2020: Worker Security and the Covid-19 Crisis,
OECD, July 2020.
94 As measured by OECD, Strictness of employment protection – individual and collective dismissals (regular contracts).
95 For a time series of involuntary dismissals, see Figure 15 in: N Cominetti et al, Changing Jobs: Change in the UK labour market and
the role of worker mobility, January 2022.
96 N Cominetti et al. Low Pay Britain 2022: Low pay and insecurity in the UK labour market, Resolution Foundation, May 2022.
97 For a full set of policy options and accompanying discussion see: A Harrop, H Reed & E Sacares, In time of need: Building
Employment Insurance for All, Fabian Society, March 2023.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
69
However, even without changing what is offered to self-employed workers, policy makers
could still drive improvements for self-employed workers by bringing more self-employed
workers within the scope of policies which relate to ‘workers. This should include
creating a clearer legal test of self-employment so that those who are truly ‘workers
(and entitled to the minimum wage) can more easily secure that status. Secondly, we
should remove the tax incentive to organise work as self-employment – this means
self-employed workers should pay the same National Insurance Contributions as
employees.
98
98 N Cominetti et al. Low Pay Britain 2022: Low pay and insecurity in the UK labour market, Resolution Foundation, May 2022.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
70
Section 6
Conclusion
The UK has made tremendous progress on eroding low pay in recent years – not progress
that we would have expected when we first started producing annual Low Pay Britain
reports in 2010. It is right to celebrate this. But we need to recognise there are still big
problems facing low earners. So rather than just celebrating the minimum wage we must
learn the lessons it gives us about what is possible, and about the choices we can make
as a country about the nature of low paid work. We can through concerted policy action
ensure everyone has a minimum level dignity at work. We have argued in this report that
priority areas for reform relate to security of one type or another, and we have highlighted
the need for a better statutory sick pay system, and protections for workers whose hours
and pay vary unexpectedly.
This report is also about how improving work should be seen as part of an overall
economic strategy. While it’s important to consider the micro trade-offs involved in
each policy area, looking at the big picture and at how our labour standards shape our
economy matters too. We will continue to develop this idea in forthcoming reports,
including through our Economy 2030 Inquiry, which will conclude in the autumn. As part
of this inquiry, and relevant to this report, we will be writing reports on the potential for
sector level bargaining to drive up employment standards, and on how our social security
system should evolve over the coming decade. Later this month (April 2023) we will also
publish a report concluding our three-year programme investigating the enforcement of
labour market rights, which is of course a vital complement to any programme of raising
minimum standards.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
71
Annex 1: Low pay in 2022
TABLE 1: Proportion and number of employees below selected hourly low paid
thresholds: GB, 2022
Number
(000s)
% of all
below
threshold
% in
group
below
threshold
Number
(000s)
% of all
below
threshold
% in
group
below
threshold
Number
(000s)
% of all
below
threshold
% in
group
below
threshold
All employees
2,525
100%
9%
1,670
100%
6%
3755
100%
13%
Sex
Men 1,065 42% 8% 690 41% 5% 1545 41% 11%
Women
1,460
58%
10%
980
59%
7%
2210
59%
16%
Age group
16-20 735 30% 57% 150 9% 12% 850 23% 66%
21-24
310
13%
16%
210
13%
11%
460
13%
24%
25-30
230
9%
6%
200
13%
5%
395
11%
10%
31-35
175
7%
5%
155
10%
5%
295
8%
9%
36-40 180 7% 5% 160 10% 5% 290 8% 9%
41-45
170
7%
5%
150
9%
5%
275
8%
9%
46-50 180 7% 6% 160 10% 5% 290 8% 9%
51-55
160
7%
5%
140
9%
5%
275
8%
9%
56-60 170 7% 6% 150 9% 6% 280 8% 11%
61-65
140
6%
9%
125
8%
8%
225
6%
14%
Region
North East 130 5% 12% 90 5% 8% 180 5% 17%
North West 310 12% 10% 205 12% 7% 425 11% 14%
Yorkshire and The Humber 245 10% 10% 170 10% 7% 410 11% 17%
East Midlands
215
8%
11%
145
9%
8%
285
8%
15%
West Midlands 270 11% 11% 195 12% 8% 355 9% 15%
South West
230
9%
10%
140
9%
6%
305
8%
13%
East 235 9% 9% 145 9% 6% 320 9% 12%
London
220
9%
5%
160
10%
4%
625
17%
15%
South East 345 14% 8% 210 13% 5% 435 12% 11%
Wales
130
5%
10%
80
5%
6%
165
4%
13%
Scotland 195 8% 8% 125 8% 5% 255 7% 10%
City region
Manchester
115
5%
10%
80
5%
7%
160
4%
14%
Birmingham 115 5% 10% 90 5% 8% 155 4% 14%
Liverpool
55
2%
10%
40
2%
7%
75
2%
14%
Leeds 120 5% 10% 80 5% 7% 235 6% 19%
Sheffield
70
3%
11%
50
3%
8%
95
3%
15%
Newcastle 95 4% 12% 65 4% 8% 135 4% 16%
Nottingham
45
2%
12%
30
2%
8%
65
2%
16%
Bristol
45
2%
7%
25
2%
4%
55
1%
9%
Glasgow
65
3%
8%
45
3%
5%
85
2%
10%
Cardiff
60
2%
9%
40
2%
6%
75
2%
12%
Tees Valley 35 1% 14% 25 1% 10% 45 1% 18%
London
220
9%
5%
160
10%
4%
625
17%
15%
East Anglia
85
3%
9%
55
3%
6%
120
3%
13%
Greater Lincolnshire 55 2% 14% 40 2% 10% 75 2% 17%
Below 2/3 median hourly pay
Near or below NLW
Below Living Wage
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
72
NOTES:At or below minimum wage’ defined as earning below the age-specific minimum wage plus 5p.
SOURCE: Analysis of ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings and New Earnings Survey Panel Dataset.
Number
(000s)
% of all
below
threshold
% in
group
below
threshold
Number
(000s)
% of all
below
threshold
% in
group
below
threshold
Number
(000s)
% of all
below
threshold
% in
group
below
threshold
Hours worked
Full time
930 37% 5% 650 39% 3% 1515 40% 8%
Part time 1,595 63% 20% 1,020 61% 13% 2240 60% 29%
Hours worked and sex
Full time men 515 20% 4% 360 22% 3% 805 22% 7%
Full time Women 415 16% 5% 290 17% 3% 705 19% 9%
Part time men 550 22% 26% 330 20% 15% 740 20% 34%
Part time Women 1,045 41% 18% 690 41% 12% 1500 40% 27%
Firm structure
Private companies 1,970 78% 11% 1,270 76% 7% 2895 77% 16%
Sole proprietors 140 6% 32% 110 7% 25% 170 4% 38%
Partnerships 105 4% 18% 70 4% 12% 140 4% 23%
Central government 70 3% 2% 50 3% 1% 145 4% 4%
Local authorities 65 2% 2% 45 3% 2% 130 4% 5%
Non-profit bodies and mutuals 165 7% 6% 125 7% 5% 265 7% 10%
Firm size
XS (0-9 employees)
570 24% 22% 450 29% 17% 695 20% 27%
S (10-49 employees) 580 24% 14% 375 24% 9% 745 22% 19%
M (50-249 employees) 325 14% 9% 210 13% 6% 480 14% 13%
L (250-4,999 employees) 490 20% 8% 310 20% 5% 795 23% 13%
XL (5,000+ employees) 420 18% 9% 225 14% 5% 755 22% 16%
Industry
Agriculture
30 1% 18% 20 1% 10% 40 1% 24%
Manufacturing 155 6% 6% 120 7% 5% 225 6% 9%
Water supply & waste 5 0% 4% 5 0% 3% 15 0% 7%
Construction 80 3% 8% 55 3% 5% 100 3% 9%
Wholesale & retail 565 23% 15% 385 23% 10% 890 24% 23%
Transport & storage 50 2% 4% 40 2% 3% 75 2% 7%
Hotels & restaurants 580 23% 39% 300 18% 20% 745 20% 50%
Info. & comms. 30 1% 3% 20 1% 2% 45 1% 4%
Finance 10 0% 1% 5 0% 1% 15 0% 2%
Real estate 25 1% 6% 20 1% 5% 40 1% 10%
Prof. & technical 85 3% 4% 60 4% 3% 125 3% 6%
Admin & support services 240 10% 14% 195 12% 11% 360 10% 21%
Public admin 15 1% 1% 10 1% 1% 30 1% 2%
Education 170 7% 4% 120 7% 3% 300 8% 8%
Health & social work 260 10% 6% 180 11% 4% 465 12% 11%
Arts & recreation 110 4% 20% 60 4% 11% 140 4% 26%
Other service activities 90 4% 18% 75 4% 14% 120 3% 23%
Below 2/3 median hourly pay
Near or below NLW
Below Living Wage
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
73
Annex 2: An illustrative example of a new
Statutory Sick Pay system
Reforms to Statutory Sick Pay would be much more generous to a typical full-time
and part-time minimum wage worker than the current system (as shown in Figure 25).
The combination of sick pay starting from day two of sickness (rather than four) and
earnings-related sick pay of 64 per cent (rather than a flat rate) would see full and part-
time minimum wage workers remuneration for a week of sickness increase considerably
compared to the existing system (by £159.43 and £64.61, respectively).
FIGURE 25: Reforms to SSP would be much more generous to typical full-time
and part-time minimum wage workers than the current system
Statutory sickness payments if a full-time and part-time minimum wage worker took
one working week of sick leave, in existing and proposed system
NOTES: Assumes a worker is on the 2023 minimum wage of £10.42/hour. Current system: £109.40/week
after 3 waiting days. Proposed system: 65% earnings replacement after 1 waiting day.
SOURCE: Analysis of Gov.uk: Overview of SSP.
£43.76
£203.19
£43.76
£108.37
£0
£50
£100
£150
£200
Current system
(£109.40 per week; 3 day wait)
Proposed system
(65 per cent earnings replacement; 1 day wait)
Works full-time (37.5 hours per week) Works part-time (20 hours per week)
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
74
Annex 3: Thinking about optimal minimum wages
In this annex we provide a brief summary of the literature which has attempted to
describe and derive an ‘optimum’ minimum wage.
As the UK and other countries raise their minimum wages to higher levels, discussion
of what is the ‘right’ level for the minimum wage becomes more relevant. Over the year,
there have been a number of discussions of the ‘optimal’ minimum wage. They rely on
making assumptions about how the labour market works, as well as deciding what is to
be optimised, for example what weight to place on employment versus wages, and how
to weight the benefits going to different groups, whilst others consider how minimum
wages interact with the tax and benefit system. This box summarises the argument
contained in some of these studies.
Economic models attempting to define an “optimal” minimum wage rate usually
account for the complexity of the employment effects that an introduction - or rise
in minimum wage - implies. Dickens, Machin and Manning
99
, for example, state that
once faced with an increase in the minimum wage, firms may find themselves in three
different “regions” with respect to the new wage floor: demand-constrained, supply-
constrained or unconstrained. In the first case, demand-constrained firms are firms for
which the minimum wage is always binding and who are forced up their demand curve
by a minimum wage increase, which results in employment losses. The second regime,
covering supply-constrained firms, are characterised by firm market power and where an
increase in the wage floor acts as a countervailing force to reduce such power, so they
pay higher and productively viable wages that can generate employment gains. Finally,
unconstrained firms pay wages considerably higher than any of the minimum wage rates
even when exerting labour market power and hence, in absence of reallocation effects,
their employment remains unchanged. Figure 1 from the recent Berger, Herkenoff and
Mongey study (copied below) is a good illustrative example of the three “regions” in which
a firm can be situated when a minimum wage is set (or increased) and how it can lead
to employment losses, gains and reallocation simultaneously in the same labour market
depending on the composition and labour market power of the firms operating in it
100
.
99 R. Dickens, S. Machin and A. Manning, ‘The Effects of Minimum Wages on Employment, January 1999
100 D. Berger, K. Herkenhoff and S. Mongey, ‘Minimum wages, Efficiency and Welfare, January 2022
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
75
In order to gauge and estimate the overall net direction of employment effects of
minimum wages required for an ‘optimal’ minimum wage level, recent research relies on
models of the labour market (‘general equilibrium’ models) which include assumptions
about various margins of the adjustment and degrees of competitiveness in the labour
market. Ahlfeldt, Roth and Seidel propose a spatial equilibrium model in the context
of Germany’s introduction of a federal minimum wage which allows for firms with
different levels of productivity and variations in monoposonistic labour market power by
exploring individual preferences for residence and workplace.
101
In a similar spirit, Berger,
Herkenoff and Mongey study the effect of federal minimum wages in the US within a
general equilibrium model which also allows for heterogeneity in firms productivity
but adds heterogeneity of workers in productivity and other dimensions. Crucially, the
modelling also assumes a departure from perfectly competitive labour markets with the
introduction of labour market power by firms that can be described as an oligopsonistic
labour market where firms compete over workers.
Both models are able to produce results in line with some of the evidence previously
debated: a lack of aggregate disemployment effects at lower minimum wage levels,
a reallocation of workers from less productive firms to more productive firms, and a
positive effect on hiring, retention and turnover (not explicitly within firms but rather
across firms). Ultimately, in both cases, the calculation of an ‘optimal’ level of minimum
wage implies balancing the efficiency and redistribution gains resulting from eroding
101 G. Ahlfeldt, D. Roth and T. Seide ‘Optimal Minimum Wages, January 2022
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
76
the labour market power of unconstrained and supply-constrained firms versus the
efficiency and redistribution losses of forcing firms to be demand-constrained in labour
markets with considerably different levels of labour market power.
The conclusions of the types of models describing the “optimal’ minimum wage level
need to be caveated against a range of departures from the model assumptions, and
their interaction with other labour market policies that affect low wage workers. This is
an active research field. The main message for policy makers is perhaps not so unfamiliar
to those working in this field: testing small increments on national level minimum wages,
and carefully evaluating employment effects, together with other modes of adjustment to
minimum wage changes, can usefully inform discussions of optimal minimum wages, and
possible variations in mandated wage floors.
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
77
Reports published as part of The
Economy 2030 Inquiry to date
All publications are available on the Inquiry’s website.
1. The UK’s decisive decade: The launch report of The Economy 2030 Inquiry
2. Levelling up and down Britain: How the labour market recovery varies across the
country
3. Work experiences: Changes in the subjective experience of work
4. The Carbon Crunch: Turning targets into delivery
5. Trading places: Brexit and the path to longer-term improvements in living standards
6. Business time: How ready are UK firms for the decisive decade?
7. Begin again? Assessing the permanent implications of Covid-19 for the UK’s labour
market
8. Social mobility in the time of Covid: Assessing the social mobility implications of
Covid-19
9. Changing jobs? Change in the UK labour market and the role of worker mobility
10. Social Insecurity: Assessing trends in social security to prepare for the decade of
change ahead
11. A presage to India: Assessing the UK’s new Indo-Pacific trade focus
12. Under pressure: Managing fiscal pressures in the 2020s
13. Under new management: How immigration policy will, and won’t, affect the UK’s
path to becoming a high-wage, high-productivity economy
14. Shrinking footprints: The impacts of the net zero transition on households and
consumption
15. Enduring strengths: Analysing the UK’s current and potential economic strengths,
and what they mean for its economic strategy, at the start of the decisive decade
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
78
16. Listen up: Individual experiences of work, consumption and society
17. Growing clean: Identifying and investing in sustainable growth opportunities across
the UK
18. Low Pay Britain 2022: Low pay and insecurity in the UK labour market
19. Bouncebackability: The UK corporate sectors recovery from Covid-19
20. All over the place: Perspectives on local economic prosperity
21. Right where you left me? Analysis of the Covid-19 pandemic’s impact on local
economies in the UK
22. Big welcomes and long goodbyes: The impact of demographic change in the 2020s
23. Net zero jobs: The impact of the transition to net zero on the UK labour market
24. The Big Brexit: An assessment of the scale of change to come from Brexit
25. Income outcomes: Assessing income gaps between places across the UK
26. Bridging the gap: What would it take to narrow the UK’s productivity disparities?
27. Power plays: The shifting balance of employer and worker power in the UK labour
market
28. Stagnation nation: Navigating a route to a fairer and more prosperous Britain
29. As good as it gets? The forces driving economic stagnation and what they mean for
the decade ahead
30. Centralisation Nation: Britains system of local government and its impact on the
national economy
31. Adopt, adapt and improve: A brief look at the interplay between labour markets and
technological change in the UK
32. Train in Vain? Skills, tasks, and training in the UK labour market
33. Hitting a brick wall: How the UK can upgrade its housing stock to reduce energy
bills and cut carbon
34. Cutting the cuts: How the public sector can play its part in ending the UK’s low-
investment rut
The Economy 2030 Inquiry | Low Pay Britain 2023
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org
The UK is on the brink of a decade of huge economic change –
from the Covid-19 recovery, to exiting the EU and transitioning
towards a Net Zero future. The Economy 2030 Inquiry will examine
this decisive decade for Britain, and set out a plan for how we can
successfully navigate it.
The Inquiry is a collaboration between the Resolution Foundation
and the Centre for Economic Performance at the London School
of Economics. It is funded by the Nuffield Foundation.
For more information on The Economy 2030 Inquiry, visit
economy2030.resolutionfoundation.org.
For more information on this report, contact:
Nye Cominetti
Senior Economist
nye.cominetti@resolutionfoundation.org
Funded by